Dopp: 13:“Costly. …”

The two main expenses associated with the transition to IRV are voting equipment upgrades and voter education. Both of these are one-time costs that will be quickly balanced out by the savings coming from eliminating a runoff election in each election cycle. In San Francisco, for example, the city and county saved approximately $3 million by not holding a separate runoff election in 2005, easily covering the mostly one-time costs spent in 2003-2004 to implement the system.

There are some strong assumptions being made here. There are increased counting costs that are ongoing. Consider this: there are a number of jurisdictions, like Oakland, which have "adopted" IRV "pending implementation." I.e., if they can get the money to do the conversion and education. If it saves so much money, one would think it would be a good investment, that the City of Oakland would rush to do it.

There are a number of issues that get mashed together here.

First, twice FairVote mentioned Robert's Rules of Order as stating that Preferential Voting was more fair than Plurality. However, what they describe is the method of STV with a true majority requirement, the election will have to be repeated under some circumstances, i.e., where, after transfers, no candidate gains a majority of ballots cast, due to exhausted ballots. Robert's Rules doesn't just prefer repeated balloting if there is no majority found, it *requires* it. It takes a bylaw to change that. This is about majority rule, and some think that important. I know I do. And cities which have adopted Top-Two Runoff apparently think so too, and were willing to cover the extra cost for the benefits of that.

IRV does not find those majority winners. It's a trick, smoke and mirrors, making it look like there was a majority, if you only look at the last round, pretending that this was an actual runoff, where people show up and vote among those two options. But RCV, with a three-rank ballot, doesn't even allow some sincere voters that privilege. Further, in nonpartisan elections, and the vast majority of these RCV elections are actually nonpartisan, RCV tends very strongly to simple ratify the results of the first round, because the vote transfers tend to happen in the same ratio as the already existing votes. This is the point about partisan elections: voters and candidates aren't neatly organized by political preference, and, it turns out that, if C is eliminated, the C votes will be split up in about the same ratio as A:B already have.

In a real runoff, however, something different happens. I can theorize as to why that happens, but the fact is that it does. There are "comebacks." I found one-third comeback elections in my small study, FairVote, in a larger one, found 29%.

Let me say what this means to me. In something on the order of one-third of IRV elections that are taking place, there is an instant runoff. I think we can pretty much assume that the same proportion of runoffs would occur with TTR. And in a little less than one out of three runoffs there is a comeback. There are no comebacks happening in these nonpartisan IRV elections, and so I conclude that about one time out of ten, IRV is choosing the wrong winner, i.e., choosing a winner other than what democratic process, as recommended by Robert's Rules of Order, would choose. Robert's Rules of Order specifically notes this drawback of the STV method. It *greatly* prefers that there be repeated balloting.

IRV choosing the wrong winner isn't "rare." It's about one election out of ten. Those comebacks are important to democracy. And we've been deceived about them. Top-two runoff gives real room for third parties, if used for partisan elections. Consider what happens if a minor party candidate manages to move up to second place in the first round. Suddenly all bets are off. There will be a real campaign where the major party candidate involved will have to take the third party seriously. The supporters of the third party will be highly motivated to turn out to vote. It becomes a real race. This isn't just theory, it happens, in France for example.

We already have an advanced election system in place, it's called top-two runoff. We should use it more, not less. It can be improved. Using IRV for the first round would be an improvement, but pretty expensive. It looks like it would avoid less than one out of three runoffs. That's why I suggest Approval or Bucklin for the first round. Bucklin is probably the most efficient of the four methods (Plurality, IRV, Approval, and Bucklin) at finding majorities. The problem with IRV is that it conceals votes, some votes are never counted in determining the winner. Some second rank votes are important, some aren't. FairVote touts Later-no-Harm as a big feature of IRV, but, in fact, it is the cause of its failure, the cause of Robert's Rules criticism of the method.

In my mind, cost is an issue, but is secondary to democratic values. Majority rule is a basic democratic value. IRV has been sold as a way to satisfy "majority rule," but, if those who said that knew what they were talking about, they were lying. Most of those saying that are simply deceived, they haven't looked at the details, and you know what is said about the devil and the details. IRV frustrates majority rule almost as badly, i.e., as often, as Plurality can.

In North Carolina, counties spent $3.5 million for the Superintendent of Public Instruction runoff in 2004, an election with a statewide turnout of only 3%. In 2007, IRV elections in Cary (NC) avoided the need for a runoff in one of the city council districts that would have cost taxpayers $28,000.

Runoffs in Cary are held with the November general election. They are therefore relatively cheap. Did Cary save money? I haven't seen any analysis that shows that? They did have a lot of problems counting their experimental IRV election.

An effective voter education program can also be done for relatively little money by learning from what types of education worked well in other jurisdictions and what types did not – with the biggest factors being a good ballot design, clear voter instructions and effective pollworker training, in that order. In a report to the Vermont General Assembly, the Vermont Secretary of State estimated that, based on how well IRV was implemented in Vermont’s largest city of Burlington in 2006, voter education for statewide IRV in Vermont would cost less than $0.25 per registered voter. In a city of more than 100,000 people, Cary spent less than $10,000 on voter education – with highly favorable reactions from voters.

The analysis is coming from someone paid to promote IRV. Indications I get from North Carolina is that Cary is not at all eager to repeat the experiment.

But the bottom line is that we could save a *lot* of money by not holding any elections at all. Couldn't we? Or how about selecting a random jury of twelve to make decisions? After all, we allow juries of twelve to make life and death decisions routinely.

14. Dopp: “Increases the potential for undetectable vote fraud and erroneous vote counts…"

Actually, just the opposite is true, so long as paper ballots (such as optical scan) are used. The reason that any attempts at fraud are easier to detect with IRV is that there is a redundant electronic record (called a ballot image) of each ballot that can be matched one-to-one with the corresponding paper ballot. Cities such as San Francisco (CA) and Burlington (VT) release these ballot files so that any voter can do their own count. Without such redundant ballot records (which are not typical with vote-for-one elections) there is no way to know for certain if the paper ballots have been altered prior to a recount.

Dopp is the voting security expert, against Rob Richie, the huckster paid for years to promote IRV, regardless of whether it's an improvement or not, paying no attention to voting systems researchers and academics. "Any voter can do their own count"? Try it.

But this is an entirely different issue. Those ballot "images" aren't images. They are the result of ballot analysis by the equipment, not just the results of scans. They have been altered, that is, they do not show what marks were made on the paper unless those marks met certain rules. For example, if there is an overvote in first choice, but normal votes for second and third choice, all those subsequent votes are read by the equipment, I'm sure, but the equipment is then programmed to put undervotes into the "images."

Isn't that just slightly disturbing?

Continued with:
Dopp: 15. “Violates some election fairness principles…."

----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to