At 02:56 PM 8/30/2013, Richard Fobes wrote:
Abd ~

Thank you for warning us about this Wikipedia article ("Electoral reform in the United States") being a battleground partly populated with IRV-FairVote soldiers.

I'm choosing other "fronts" for my election-method reform efforts, which is why I don't have time for these edits.

Richard Fobes
(aka VoteFair)

Well, the article was most recently heavily edited by http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/User:DavidMCEddy

This editor does not appear to me to be a "FairVote soldier," but only an ordinary editor, not terribly sophisticated as to Wikipedia RS requirements, just trying to make the article more complete and to improve it in certain ways.

Rather, early editing on the article was done by someone who actually was a "FairVote solider." Or who became one for a time.

I don't see the article as a true "battleground" yet. It has not attracted enough attention. Mostly it's been neglected.

My *general conclusion* about Wikipedia is that editing it can be far, far too cumbersome, and the results are unstable, whenever "battleground" conditions arise. One can go to enormous lengths to develop editorial consensus. Look back a few years later, and the results may have disappeared, with old, already resolved issues, being asserted again.

I could show examples from the Instant Runoff Voting article. I'll provide a clue.

In theory, there should be no references in the lede of the article, which briefly explains the topic and *what is not controversial about it.* But when an article becomes a battleground, a faction will want to assert its position in the lede, and then may be challenged, and so references are added. But that misses the point. To put something in the lede is not just about "truth," or "verifiability," but rather establishes the context in which the article will be read. A POV faction will cherry-pick the available facts to assert them in the lede. Perhaps only "positive" or "negative" facts will be so asserted.

From the current lede for the IRV article, you would have no clue that there is any controversy over it. There is only promotional information. I notice that FairVote is still cited as if FairVote were Reliable Source. By definition, it is not. It's an advocacy organization. At one point, all this was cleaned out. FairVote was listed as an advocacy organization. That's been removed, because it's listed as if it were a "reliable source," and it is generally not done to add additional links to reliable sources, i.e., to sites already referenced in the article.

Everything in the lede should be covered in the article, and that is where references would be (or sometimes, a partiuclar point is covered in another article, which will be cited in the main body of the article, and references might be there. Again, such a summary should reflect high consensus.

User RRichie continues to edit the article. Rob's edits are often helpful, but he has a consistent point of view. (He was actually blocked at one point, for behavior violating policy, while editing anonymously. I confronted that, it was my first experience with enforcing Wikipedia policy. I also supported his unblocking, provided he edited open with disclosed conflict of interest. The same with our friend from Vermont, Terry Bouricius. He'd also been blocked because he'd been supporting the anonymous Richie and a sock puppet of another banned editor.

I became much more involved in Wikipedia policy in general, and moved away from tending the IRV article.

There has been, perhaps, a little slippage on the matter of IRV and Robert's Rules of Order.

http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Instant-runoff_voting#Robert.27s_Rules_of_Order

Originally, Robert's Rules was listed in the lede as recommending IRV. I added to that the rather negative comments in RRONR about the method. It is suggested only as an option, based on actual practice, not as a normative suggestion. And the method they actually describe is critically different from what is implemented on FairVote recommendations. I requires a true majority for election, not the faux "last round majority."

FairVote argued bitterly against this. I was called a liar, even though it was blatantly clear from RRONR. Now, with my later perspective, with much more experience with Wikipedia policy, I was doing a kind of Original Research. That is sometimes allowed, and so, about this point, maybe. In the end, it would depend on editorial consensus, but if only one faction is paying attention to an article, there you go! I see it all the time: a faction slips in an edit and nobody notices.

I've seen totally outrageous edits, seriously violating policy, slipped in, nobody noticed, and even when the editor is banned, nobody does anything about it, because it simply isn't realized the implications of the edit. Only someone who is aware of the various POVs and how they are pushed will notice it.

Notice the implication from the RRO section: repeated balloting is "impractical." Yet the most widely implemented election reform, for over a century, has been real runoff voting. It's obviously not intrinsically impractical! RRONR points out the serious problems raised by IRV, and the RRONR version asserts those *even if a majority is required*. They would never recommend the FairVote version of IRV, not for single-winner elections.

So the text, "and then the instant runoff voting method is detailed" is *wrong.*

That text is an example of synthesis, of the interpretation of a source by an editor. Essentially, RRONR does "detail" a method. Is that method the same as IRV? It is certainly similar, but there is a critical difference. They never redefine "majority," as the IRV method as applied under FairVote recommendations does. The RRONR description is quite explicit: if there is no majority found, the election *fails and must be repeated.* They don't give accepting a plurality result as an option, and the definition of majority used by FairVote *cannot fail to be found,* because, essentially, all contrary votes have been eliminated, excluded from the basis for majority.

This is one way that FairVote has managed to promote deception: they have discovered facts, that if alleged, are defensible as true, at least in some way. If the fact is alleged, people then make certain assumptions. The *counting method* is generally described, and I remember how long it took me to notice the actual difference between the FairVote method and the RRONR method, so thoroughly had I been led -- by the FairVote quoting of that section, which they actually do quote -- into thinking that this was "IRV." It is *exactly* the method, with only one exception!

A crucial exception, that, if applied to, say, the San Francisco RCV elections, would require many of them -- almost everyone where there was an "instant runoff -- to be repeated, thus kind of blowing the utility of RCV out of the water!

Now, what can be done about this? I don't know. Wikipedia process is so cumbersome that no particular approach is reliable. It is often a matter of convincing "neutral editors" that a change is okay. The problem is that "neutral editors" generally are ignorant on the topic, and easily misled. It can be very tricky. Wikipedia is "anti-expert." There is something appealing about this, but it also leads to serious problems where accurate interpetation of sources is involved. Non-experts may easily misunderstand sources!

In this case, a parliamentarian would quickly realize the implications of "majority." But most editors aren't parliamentarians!

Here is a remarkable recent edit that can illustrate the problem:

http://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Instant-runoff_voting&diff=561293057&oldid=560680057

The editor claims, in his edit summary, that

(There is no such thing as an "absolutely majority" (nor, a correctly spelled "absolute majority"). A majority is defined as more than half.

There was an obvious error there, but in voting system descriptions, "absolute majority" refers to "majority of the votes." It's distinct from the IRV "last round majority," or the "majority of votes for candidates not yet eliminated. In Australia -- and Wikipedia is about the world, not just the United States, for sure -- the term "absolute majority" is used with the "majority of all the votes" meaning, that is, all *legal votes.* Australia requires that, to be a legal vote, and in "absolute majority" jurisdictions, the voter rank *all* the candidates, so an absolute majority is guaranteed by the rules. In some Australian jurisdictions, "OPV," or Optional Preferential Voting, is allowed, and the term "absolute majority" is then changed to the modified majority that excludes some legal votes as part of the basis.

This editor still left "absolute majority" in the text, a few words later. The change was not wrong, but betrays an ignorance of the issues.

The section on IRV procedure is effectively designed to be "true" but to suppress recognition of the difference:

The process repeats until one candidate achieves a majority of votes cast for continuing candidates. Ballots that 'exhaust' all their preferences (all its ranked candidates are eliminated) are set aside.

Notice the inserted phrase "cast for continuing candidates." That excludes many votes, such that, *often*, IRV winners don't actually have the support of a majority of voters, in spite of major propaganda in implementation campaigns that IRV is a way to find such majorities. Thet explantion, "set aside," matches the RRONR description. Those ballots are literally "set aside" in manual counting procedures, i.e., they are no longer counted. But what does not change in the RRONR procedure is the definition of majority. It was calculated at the beginning, in the first round, and it remains the same.

Most people don't think of or realize the implications of candidate elimination. They tend to think very simply, of a situation like Gore v. Bush v. Nader. They think of eliminated candidates as minor ones. Yet, in fact, IRV can eliminate a candidate who would, in a pairwise election, beat every other candidate, but this candidate simply has less first-preference votes than two others. Lower-preference votes for the candidate may exist, underneath votes for the "top two" as identified by IRV. That is, IRV can decide a winner *against* the expressed preference of a majority, and it's been known to do that. This is why RRONR criticizes IRV, when they refer to a "compromise choice." That means a choice that is *actually acceptable to a majority of voters.*

Every attempt to explain this in the article was shot down by FairVote advocates. It's not that they have the power to control the article. It's that they became skilled in presenting misleading arguments.
----
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info

Reply via email to