Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-11-04 Thread Bryan Caplan
Robin Hanson wrote:

 Now maybe you accept this, and think yourself part of, or advisor to, an
 elite empowered to make ordinary people do things that are good for them,
 whether they like it or not.  

I think that what Bill might say is that even though people under-invest
in their own education, they are in fact quite willing to vote for
education spending.  He might even suggest that qua voters, people
recognize and adjust for their failings as consumers.  Akerlof and
Dickens make a similar argument about retirement savings in *An
Economist's Book of Tales*.

 But here's the
 crucial question:  how sure are you that you and your fellow advisors, and
 the elites you advise, are substantially less irrational in this process of
 making ordinary people do things that are good for them?  Can't elite
 advisors be irrational too?   

I think Bill would say that he's pretty sure.  He's seen the data,
crunched the numbers, read the literature, etc.  If you feel comfortable
failing people on their exams, why shouldn't you feel comfortable giving
them a failing grade on their decision-making outside of the classroom?

But perhaps I'm making Bill sound a little too much like me!
-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-11-04 Thread AdmrlLocke

In a message dated 11/4/02 4:30:31 PM, [EMAIL PROTECTED] writes:

 I think Bill would say that he's pretty sure.  He's seen the data,
crunched the numbers, read the literature, etc.  If you feel comfortable
failing people on their exams, why shouldn't you feel comfortable giving
them a failing grade on their decision-making outside of the classroom? 

It's one thing to say that someone has failed the narrow task of grasping the 
subject matter of one class, and quite another to say that someone has failed 
the make the right choices in life.  The first involved only making a 
narrow technical assessment; the second a broad moral judgement of the sort 
that I thought went out of style with the 19th century movement of WASP 
elites to Americanize all the foolish foreign immigrants (or at least with 
the 1950s attempt to force everyone into the same bland, homogenized 
soul-less mainstream religion in the name of fighting godless Communism).

Still, I believe that people are entitled to their judgements, however 
inappropriate they may be, but it's a third thing entirely to think oneself 
entitled to use the government's monopoly (or near-monopoly in the American 
case) of legitimized use or threat of force to make people behave according 
to one's own moral judgements.

David Levenstam




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-11-04 Thread Robin Hanson
Bryan Caplan wrote:

 Now maybe you accept this, and think yourself part of, or advisor to, an
 elite empowered to make ordinary people do things that are good for them,
 whether they like it or not.

I think that what Bill might say is that even though people under-invest
in their own education, they are in fact quite willing to vote for
education spending.  He might even suggest that qua voters, people
recognize and adjust for their failings as consumers.  Akerlof and
Dickens make a similar argument about retirement savings in *An
Economist's Book of Tales*.


I know that Bryan Caplan would say that people as consumers and people as
voters are just two different sets of preferences, and there is no particular
reason to expect much consistency between them.  But that's a pretty unusual
position, so I didn't necessarily expect Bill to agree with it.  The theory
that people as voters recognize and adjust for their failings as consumers
works a lot better for self-control problems than for ignorance problems.
If people as voters know that people as consumers should get more college,
then why don't they just go get more college as consumers?


 But here's the
 crucial question:  how sure are you that you and your fellow advisors, and
 the elites you advise, are substantially less irrational in this process of
 making ordinary people do things that are good for them?  Can't elite
 advisors be irrational too?

I think Bill would say that he's pretty sure.  He's seen the data,
crunched the numbers, read the literature, etc.  If you feel comfortable
failing people on their exams, why shouldn't you feel comfortable giving
them a failing grade on their decision-making outside of the classroom?


But under the theories of irrationality that the topic here, people can be
quite wrong, and irrationally wrong, even when they feel comfortable and
feel pretty sure.  If you're going to posit an irrational ability to reason
and accept advise in ordinary people, you must be willing to posit such
phenomena in elites and their advisors.  At which point just feeling sure
is not enough.


Robin Hanson  [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://hanson.gmu.edu
Asst. Prof. Economics, George Mason University
MSN 1D3, Carow Hall, Fairfax VA 22030-
703-993-2326  FAX: 703-993-2323





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-11-04 Thread Bryan D Caplan
Robin Hanson wrote:

 I know that Bryan Caplan would say that people as consumers and people as
 voters are just two different sets of preferences, and there is no particular
 reason to expect much consistency between them.  But that's a pretty unusual
 position, so I didn't necessarily expect Bill to agree with it.  The theory
 that people as voters recognize and adjust for their failings as consumers
 works a lot better for self-control problems than for ignorance problems.
 If people as voters know that people as consumers should get more college,
 then why don't they just go get more college as consumers?

Avoiding all responsibility by arguing another person's view is fun. 
Given what Bill said earlier, the most natural position for him seems to
be precisely that people suffer a self-control problem when they make
personal schooling choices.  After all, he says that people overestimate
the return to schooling, but underinvest relative to the actual, lower
rate.  And he points to over-emphasis on immediate pleasure and pain. 
Fits the usual self-control mold.

 But under the theories of irrationality that the topic here, people can be
 quite wrong, and irrationally wrong, even when they feel comfortable and
 feel pretty sure.  If you're going to posit an irrational ability to reason
 and accept advise in ordinary people, you must be willing to posit such
 phenomena in elites and their advisors.  

You always say this.  Why?  The fact that *those dummies* are irrational
and don't realize this hardly implies that I might be one of those
dummies.  Dogs are stupid and don't realize this.  It hardly implies
that I might be as dumb as a dog.

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
I was so convinced that soon, very soon, by some
 extraordinary circumstance I should suddenly become
 the wealthiest and most distinguished person in the
 world that I lived in constant tremulous expectation 
 of some magic good fortune befalling me. I was 
 always expecting that *it was about to begin* and I 
 on the point of attaining all that man could desire, 
 and I was forever hurrying from place to place, 
 believing that 'it' must be 'beginning' just where I 
 happened not to be.
Leo Tolstoy, *Youth*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-29 Thread Robin Hanson
On 10/25/02, William Dickens wrote:

... the rationality assumptions built into to any inter-temporal 
optimizing model are so demanding that sort of trying to get it right 
will get you no where near the predictions of the of the 
full-rationality-perfect-information model. The deviations are significant 
both for the individual and for the policy implications. Take saving for 
retirement. A little irrationality and mandatary saving can cause big 
increases in welfare.  Take college choice. ... people seem to be 
amazingly uninformed. Anybody who says oh well, there probably getting it 
approximately right, is kidding him/herself. ... Nearly everyone should 
get more schooling than they do. This is only one of many intertemporal 
decisions that people badly screw up because they aren't good at thinking 
about the future vs. the present.

You are assuming that the only way to make good decisions about retirement 
or college is via direct calculation of costs and benefits across time.  An 
obvious alternative, however, is to rely on the advice of knowledgeable 
experts.  For example, if people would just listen to one William Dickens, 
they would know to save more for retirement and get more schooling.  So in 
order for irrationality to produce bad decisions about retirement and 
school, people must not only be bad at thinking about the future, they must 
also be bad at thinking about whether to take advice from you and similar 
advisors.

Now I am willing to believe that many, perhaps most, people are in fact 
bad, even irrational, at taking advice.  But even so, it is hard to see how 
it would make sense for an accountable democratic government to push or 
force people to save or go to school more.   If people don't think they 
need more savings or school, it is hard to see how they would want their 
government to push them into doing so.  So if governments are going to help 
irrational citizens by pushing them toward more savings and schooling, it 
would have to be because such governments are run by not-especially 
accountable elites.

Now maybe you accept this, and think yourself part of, or advisor to, an 
elite empowered to make ordinary people do things that are good for them, 
whether they like it or not.  Maybe you accept that, if asked, ordinary 
people would not authorize this elite to act this way, and would not accept 
this elite's advice regarding how they should behave.  But here's the 
crucial question:  how sure are you that you and your fellow advisors, and 
the elites you advise, are substantially less irrational in this process of 
making ordinary people do things that are good for them?  Can't elite 
advisors be irrational too?   For example, might not the self-interest of 
academics, as sellers of schooling, bias their advice on schooling?



Robin Hanson  [EMAIL PROTECTED]  http://hanson.gmu.edu
Asst. Prof. Economics, George Mason University
MSN 1D3, Carow Hall, Fairfax VA 22030-
703-993-2326  FAX: 703-993-2323




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-29 Thread Bryan Caplan
I have a lot to say in response to Bill on this topic.  In fact, I was
too fascinated with the topic to sleep well last night.  I'm going to
begin by answering a few specific points, then give one longer post.

William Dickens wrote:
 
 If the decision is literally a no-brainer, then failing to consider
 alternatives is rational.
 
 ??!!! Not if they make the wrong choice! OK, I suppose you are going to argue 
that all the people who didn't have a clue what the return to continuing their 
education was are the ones for whom it was a no brainer and the ones who were about 
to drop out all answered my questions correctly. I can't prove that wrong but do you 
really believe that was what was going on?

I doubt that the marginal students were more accurate on *average*
returns.  But I strongly suspect that the marginal students would have
been more pessimistic about *their own* returns.  The students who drop
out are precisely the ones who say and think I don't know if I'm really
getting much out of college.  That thought rarely occurs to stronger
students.

 The only evidence I have on this (my survey of Berkeley undergrads taking 
intermediate macro) suggests that they over estimate the percentage return as well. 
However, I don't think people act on this information. It is my strong impression 
that people tremendously overweight their current feelings of happiness or 
unhappiness about being in school so that on net people don't get as much schooling 
as they should if they were truly utility maximizes.

So what is the behavioral deviation you're talking about?  It doesn't
seem to be a judgmental bias problem - that cuts in the opposite
direction.  Is it a self-control problem?  I think you're conflating
behavioral anomalies with high discount rates and/or high disutility of
school.  The latter two are perfectly consistent with utility
maximization.

 - - Bill
 
 William T. Dickens
 The Brookings Institution
 1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
 Washington, DC 20036
 Phone: (202) 797-6113
 FAX: (202) 797-6181
 E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 AOL IM: wtdickens

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-29 Thread Bryan Caplan
William Dickens wrote:
 
 I see Bill already answered my question.
 
 Not the way you think. See my response to yours.
 
 I should also add that the social costs of tuition are much higher than
 the private costs for public universities, making it even more likely
 that the social return is quite low.
 
 I happen to believe the public good argument for education, but even if I didn't, 
you know as well as I do that you can't attribute the entire cost of the university 
to its educational product. A big chunk is paying for research. Take that out and I 
doubt the costs would be so high. After all, no reason why a college education would 
have to cost that much more than HS unless you want all Profs to be researchers.  - - 
1.  Budget/students is an overestimate.  Much less clear that
unsubsidized tuition is an overestimate.  So what cost are you willing
to assign to teaching?  In-state tuition?  Out of state tuition?  If
students would have lived at home otherwise, you should also count room
and board, minus parental grocery savings.

2.  You can think of a lot of research as consumption for faculty.  If
you have to give them that consumption to make them teach, then you
should count the costs of research when you calculate the return to
education.  There is a bit of a granularity problem (one more student
may not require any more research), but if you encourage 1% more kids to
go to college, you're going to have to pay for roughly 1% more research.

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Bryan Caplan
A belated reply to Bill.

William Dickens wrote:

 Note its the _parents_ in your story who are groaning, not the kids.
 OK, I'll admit that the no idea was based on what I know it was like
 when I was going to college in the 70s. However, it is still my
 impression after 13 years of teaching college that the vast majority of
 college students not only have never done a present value computation
 about their decision to go to school, but have never seriously
 considered the alternative of not going to school - - what they could
 do, how much they could make, what their lives would be like etc.

If the decision is literally a no-brainer, then failing to consider
alternatives is rational.  Marginal students frequently weigh continuing
vs. dropping out (just like they weigh attending vs. not attending!).

 Are you thinking only of economics majors? Business and economics
 majors (some) think this way. Do you think the average lit major is?
 Psych? Pol. Sci?

Yes.  In fact, right after a lit major tells you his major, he
frequently comments on his low expected earnings.  I'm a lit major. 
Not much money in that, but I like it.
 
 Standard economic model assumes that most of the costs are forgone
 earnings. Mom and Dad paying for school should be small potatoes (since
 you can always go to a state school at low cost). My impression is that
 this factor ways in people's decisions way out of proportion to its
 economic value.

Maybe back in the '70's.  Now in-state tuition is significant.  At Mason
it's $4400.  If you add in housing (as you should if you would have
lived at home otherwise), it's up to about $10,000.  About the annual
pay of a minimum wage job before taxes.

 But more
 to the point, I doubt that parents are making any sort of intertemporal
 comparison in paying for kids school. How many do you think have thought
 Well, if I invest the money I'm paying for the kids school in corporate
 AAAs at 6.5% his income from my bequest will be $XX, in 20XX whereas
 if I pay for his school it will be... No way. What they think is
 better to teach a man to fish than to buy him fish... or something
 like that and they fork over the bucks to  U. Not the economic model
 at all.  

I grant that few open Excel and punch in the numbers.  You could improve
their decision-making by teaching them to do so.  But if college grads
earned only 10% more than non-college grads, parents would be a lot less
quick to parrot old cliches about fishing.

Incidentally, most of your arguments (here and later in this discussion)
suggest that people over-estimate the return to education.  Is that your
real view?

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Bryan Caplan
Eric Crampton wrote:
 
 On Fri, 25 Oct 2002, William Dickens wrote:
 
  continue schooling largely under weights the future benefits. Nearly
  everyone should get more schooling than they do. This is only one of

I see Bill already answered my question.  Blunt reaction: Come on!  If
you really think most students are failing to considering foregone
earnings, and these are the big cost of school, then the problem goes in
the other direction.

I should also add that the social costs of tuition are much higher than
the private costs for public universities, making it even more likely
that the social return is quite low.
-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread William Dickens
If the decision is literally a no-brainer, then failing to consider
alternatives is rational.  

??!!! Not if they make the wrong choice! OK, I suppose you are going to argue that 
all the people who didn't have a clue what the return to continuing their education 
was are the ones for whom it was a no brainer and the ones who were about to drop out 
all answered my questions correctly. I can't prove that wrong but do you really 
believe that was what was going on?

Marginal students frequently weigh continuing
vs. dropping out (just like they weigh attending vs. not attending!).

Agreed, but it is my contention that they don't deal with the future returns in a 
way an economist would judge as rational. 

Incidentally, most of your arguments (here and later in this discussion)
suggest that people over-estimate the return to education.  Is that your
real view?

If you ask people to think about it my guess is that the average person attending a 
four year college will give you a response suggesting that they over estimate how 
much money they will make either when they graduate or if they drop out. The only 
evidence I have on this (my survey of Berkeley undergrads taking intermediate macro) 
suggests that they over estimate the percentage return as well. However, I don't 
think people act on this information. It is my strong impression that people 
tremendously overweight their current feelings of happiness or unhappiness about 
being in school so that on net people don't get as much schooling as they should if 
they were truly utility maximizes. 
- - Bill

William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens





RE: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Grey Thomas
Data that includes going to college almost certainly includes SAT scores.
(I also think they correlate strongly with IQ, but haven't looked for that
data).
I'm sure that the effect of more schooling is higher on those with higher
SAT scores.

In addition, I'd guess the data includes average, rather than median, income
increases, so it is more easily skewed upward by those achieving super-rich
status (those overpaid CEOs  -- yes, I do think overpaid -- for instance).

Tom Grey

PS. part of the great benefit of this list is that, often, asking a good
question allows somebody else to answer it who has already researched it, or
part of it ... so that I don't have to.  I'm probably not too much of a free
rider.




Now I won't argue that some people who get two years of college and then
drop out without a degree might not have been better off getting a two year
degree of certification, but the first order effect is something like at
least a 6.5% increase in income for each year of school completed whether
you get a degree or not. - - Bill





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-28 Thread Jason DeBacker
Is there a significant difference in the returns to education for those 
who get schooling in top ranked programs?  I thought I remember a 
Newsweek a couple years back that had a story about SAT scores of 
successful people (two profiles were G.W. Bush and Gore so I guess it 
was around 2000), and the point they were trying to make was that those 
who make the most money generally have SATs in the 1200 and 1300s- good 
students, but not top students.  In addition, the book The Millionaire 
Next Door describes those that accumulate the most wealth as not 
necessarily being the top students or having degrees from prestigious 
universities- and, I believe the authors said that if you make $100,000 
per year or more, then years of education is negatively correlated with 
wealth.

Also, the argument that opportunity cost is the largest cost of college, 
is often used to encourage people to not worry about student loans and 
and look at more prestigious universities, but is this the case for 
those who are choosing a top school?  With tuitions at $35K + per year, 
do you make back your investment with a higher expected salary as 
compared to a school on a lower tier?

Jason DeBacker






Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-25 Thread Eric Crampton
On Fri, 25 Oct 2002, William Dickens wrote:

 continue schooling largely under weights the future benefits. Nearly
 everyone should get more schooling than they do. This is only one of

Self-serving Eric, who hopes to be an econoimcs professor, couldn't agree
more.  Demand for college professors needs to go up.

My other side couldn't disagree more strongly.  A significant percentage
of undergrads should really be in some kind of 2-year trade school
instead.  The marginal person should get less schooling.  The person in
the bottom quartile of an undergrad class would make more money by instead
enrolling in community college and learning to be an electrician or
a plumber.  Of course, this is pure assertion and is backed by nothing
more than my sense of the matter. 

Eric Crampton





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-24 Thread William Dickens
Of course, very few people, if any, are profoundly rational optimizers,
but they are approximate optimizers. 

This is always the response of mainstream economists when one points out that people 
obviously are not behaving as models predict. Unfortunately, for a lot of people that 
is where the discussion stops. The assumption seems to be that all one has to do is 
add an error term to the prediction of the standard model and all the rest of the 
results about optimality etc. go through approximately. I think in a lot of cases that 
isn't right. Fifteen years ago I was relatively lonely in making this assertion and 
trying to systematically work out the implications of various types of irrationality. 
Today I've got a lot more company. Economists in general would do well to note that 
for a wide range of policy questions approximately rational is a far cry from fully 
rational and to think carefully about the implications of less than full rationality 
for problems they are working on.  - - Bill

William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-24 Thread AdmrlLocke

In a message dated 10/24/02 10:51:12 AM, [EMAIL PROTECTED] writes:

 This is always the response of mainstream economists when one points out 
that people obviously are not behaving as models predict. Unfortunately, for 
a lot of people that is where the discussion stops. The assumption seems to 
be that all one has to do is add an error term to the prediction of the 
standard model and all the rest of the results about optimality etc. go 
through approximately. I think in a lot of cases that isn't right. Fifteen 
years ago I was relatively lonely in making this assertion and trying to 
systematically work out the implications of various types of irrationality. 
Today I've got a lot more company. Economists in general would do well to 
note that for a wide range of policy questions approximately rational is a 
far cry from fully rational and to think carefully about the implications of 
less than full rationality for problems they are working on.  - - Bill 

A lack of information hardly indicates a lack of goal-pursuit (rationality) 
nor, I suspect, would many mainstream economists be surprised to find that 
young people on average have a level of rational ignorance than adults.

DBL
GMU




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-22 Thread William Dickens

 because
 I strongly suspect that 1) people have almost no idea how much it
will
 be worth for them to continue in school, 

Gee, now you're sounding Austrian!  No idea?  Come on.  Just look at
how parents groan when their kids talk about the low-earning majors
like
sociology, and rejoice when they do CS and the like.  There's
certainly
some plausible guesstimating going on, though I agree it could be
improved if people knew the PDV formula and used Excel (as I make my
labor undergrads do).

Note its the _parents_ in your story who are groaning, not the kids.
OK, I'll admit that the no idea was based on what I know it was like
when I was going to college in the 70s. However, it is still my
impression after 13 years of teaching college that the vast majority of
college students not only have never done a present value computation
about their decision to go to school, but have never seriously
considered the alternative of not going to school - - what they could
do, how much they could make, what their lives would be like etc.


 2) most people's decisions
 about schooling have to do with how much they like it vs. how much
they
 like whatever the alternative is (and are therefore fairly short
 sighted), 

How much they like it is in turn heavily influenced by how good they
are
at school - an indirect channel for ability bias.

Fine. I'm happy to acknowledge that ability affects decisions to go
to school, but my contention is that the decision is more of a present
trade-off decision than a future vs. present trade-off as the standard
economic analysis maintains.

At least my experience with school is that most college kids are
looking
forward to $$$.  They almost never compare current fun of school with
current fun of work.

Are you thinking only of economics majors? Business and economics
majors (some) think this way. Do you think the average lit major is?
Psych? Pol. Sci? 


3) 2) is heavily influenced by whether mom and dad are willing
 to pay for you to go to school (or someone else is), and 

True, though it's not clear what the relevance is.  

Standard economic model assumes that most of the costs are forgone
earnings. Mom and Dad paying for school should be small potatoes (since
you can always go to a state school at low cost). My impression is that
this factor ways in people's decisions way out of proportion to its
economic value.

 4) whether mom
 and dad are willing to pay depends on their own views about the
return
 to education and their bequest motive and has nothing to do with any
 discount rate.

??? Isn't their view of the return to education a view about the
discount rate?

Well I suppose if you believe in perfect capital and education
markets with completely rational and identical consumers it would have
to be, but otherwise why would you think that the return to education
would have anything to do with an individual's  discount rate? But more
to the point, I doubt that parents are making any sort of intertemporal
comparison in paying for kids school. How many do you think have thought
Well, if I invest the money I'm paying for the kids school in corporate
AAAs at 6.5% his income from my bequest will be $XX, in 20XX whereas
if I pay for his school it will be... No way. What they think is
better to teach a man to fish than to buy him fish... or something
like that and they fork over the bucks to  U. Not the economic model
at all.  - - Bill
— 


William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-22 Thread William Dickens
The history majors knew they'd make less with a 
history degree, on average, but placed a higher value on doing
something they 
enjoyed then on having a higher income. 

Yes, but did they know how much of a difference it would make? I once
did a survey of students in one of my undergraduate economics classes
about their knowledge of gains from additional years of education. What
I found was that:

1. They thought the average HS graduate made about 30% more than that
person actually makes,
2. They thought the average family income was 50% above what it
actually was at the time,
3. They thought that going to college would double their income (and
would do the same for anyone - - this was early 80s before the big gains
so it wasn't anywhere near close)
4. The standard deviation of their estimates of the _average_ return to
attending college was over 15 percentage points. 

Of course I'm sure that they actually knew the answers perfectly well,
but couldn't be bothered to answer my questions accurately being the
profoundly rational optomizers that they are... ;-}
- - Bill Dickens


William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-18 Thread William Dickens
But controling for IQ isn't warranted if years of schooling is
endogenous. Kevin Lang has written extensively about these issues. - -
Bill

William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens
 [EMAIL PROTECTED] 10/17/02 19:46 PM 
Alex T Tabarrok wrote:

 Bryan's question, however, can be rephrased as not how do you explain
 the data (low ability bias and high discount rate bias) but why is it
 that ability bias appears low?  

Ability bias isn't really low.  Using the NLSY data, for example,
controlling for AFQT scores reduces the naive estimate of the return to
education from 12.6% to 7.5%.  Ability bias *after* controlling for
intelligence might be low, though.

 In other words aren't there good grounds
 for thinking that ability bias is large?  And if so how is it that
this
 doesn't show up in the data?
 
 Alex
 
 --
 Alexander Tabarrok
 Department of Economics, MSN 1D3
 George Mason University
 Fairfax, VA, 22030
 Tel. 703-993-2314
 
 and
 
 Director of Research
 The Independent Institute
 100 Swan Way
 Oakland, CA, 94621
 Tel. 510-632-1366

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*






Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-18 Thread Bryan Caplan
William Dickens wrote:
 
 But controling for IQ isn't warranted if years of schooling is
 endogenous. Kevin Lang has written extensively about these issues. - -

Could you enlighten us?

 Bill
 
 William T. Dickens
 The Brookings Institution
 1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
 Washington, DC 20036
 Phone: (202) 797-6113
 FAX: (202) 797-6181
 E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 AOL IM: wtdickens
  [EMAIL PROTECTED] 10/17/02 19:46 PM 
 Alex T Tabarrok wrote:
 
  Bryan's question, however, can be rephrased as not how do you explain
  the data (low ability bias and high discount rate bias) but why is it
  that ability bias appears low?
 
 Ability bias isn't really low.  Using the NLSY data, for example,
 controlling for AFQT scores reduces the naive estimate of the return to
 education from 12.6% to 7.5%.  Ability bias *after* controlling for
 intelligence might be low, though.
 
  In other words aren't there good grounds
  for thinking that ability bias is large?  And if so how is it that
 this
  doesn't show up in the data?
 
  Alex
 
  --
  Alexander Tabarrok
  Department of Economics, MSN 1D3
  George Mason University
  Fairfax, VA, 22030
  Tel. 703-993-2314
 
  and
 
  Director of Research
  The Independent Institute
  100 Swan Way
  Oakland, CA, 94621
  Tel. 510-632-1366
 
 --
 Prof. Bryan Caplan
Department of Economics  George Mason University
 http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
   He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one
would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not
necessary that anyone but himself should understand it.
Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-17 Thread Bryan Caplan
William Dickens wrote:
 
 As I remember the standard neo-classical answer to this is that the main
 source of endogenaity isn't ability bias but discount rate bias - - that
 people with below average discount rates get more schooling.  

I hadn't thought of that (or heard it).  Is there actually any evidence
on discount rates and educational attainment?  We both know there is a
lot of evidence on ability (IQ) and educational attainment.

High estimated returns to education are usually claimed to be evidence
of credit market imperfections.  It seems that the welfare implications
are quite different if the real problem is high discount rates.

 So if the
 question you want to know is the effect of attending high school vs.
 only going through the 11th grade for the average person the return
 appears lower if you don't take into account that the average discount
 rate of people who drop out at 11 is much higher than the average
 discount rate of those who finish high school.
 - - Bill Dickens
 
 William T. Dickens
 The Brookings Institution
 1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
 Washington, DC 20036
 Phone: (202) 797-6113
 FAX: (202) 797-6181
 E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 AOL IM: wtdickens
 
  [EMAIL PROTECTED] 10/16/02 02:13PM 
 I've occasionally heard that instrumental variables (IV) estimators of
 the return to education yield markedly higher estimates than OLS.  Is
 this true?  And how can this make any intuitive sense?  If IV is
 correcting for endogeneity, you would expect things to go the other
 way.
 Why?  With a medical treatment, you would expect endogeneity to
 understate the benefit, because sicker people are more likely to
 voluntarily seek treatment.  But with education, you would expect
 endogeneity to overstate the benefit, because able people are more
 likely to voluntarily enroll.
 --
 Prof. Bryan Caplan
Department of Economics  George Mason University
 http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
   He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one
would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not
 
necessary that anyone but himself should understand it.
Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-17 Thread Rodney F Weiher
Just a note on discount rates.  The late sociologist Ed Banfield had an entire
theory of poverty, education, crime, and in general, class distinction based
not on income but on discount rates, e.g. higher rates, less education, more
crime, lower-class behavior.

It was very intuitive in terms of a lot of observed behavior but I don't
believe he explained well how how you empirically measure individual discount
rates

Seems the name of the book was The Unheavenly City. He was influential early
on in the Nixon administration.

Rodney Weiher



Bryan Caplan wrote:

 William Dickens wrote:
 
  As I remember the standard neo-classical answer to this is that the main
  source of endogenaity isn't ability bias but discount rate bias - - that
  people with below average discount rates get more schooling.

 I hadn't thought of that (or heard it).  Is there actually any evidence
 on discount rates and educational attainment?  We both know there is a
 lot of evidence on ability (IQ) and educational attainment.

 High estimated returns to education are usually claimed to be evidence
 of credit market imperfections.  It seems that the welfare implications
 are quite different if the real problem is high discount rates.

  So if the
  question you want to know is the effect of attending high school vs.
  only going through the 11th grade for the average person the return
  appears lower if you don't take into account that the average discount
  rate of people who drop out at 11 is much higher than the average
  discount rate of those who finish high school.
  - - Bill Dickens
 
  William T. Dickens
  The Brookings Institution
  1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
  Washington, DC 20036
  Phone: (202) 797-6113
  FAX: (202) 797-6181
  E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  AOL IM: wtdickens
 
   [EMAIL PROTECTED] 10/16/02 02:13PM 
  I've occasionally heard that instrumental variables (IV) estimators of
  the return to education yield markedly higher estimates than OLS.  Is
  this true?  And how can this make any intuitive sense?  If IV is
  correcting for endogeneity, you would expect things to go the other
  way.
  Why?  With a medical treatment, you would expect endogeneity to
  understate the benefit, because sicker people are more likely to
  voluntarily seek treatment.  But with education, you would expect
  endogeneity to overstate the benefit, because able people are more
  likely to voluntarily enroll.
  --
  Prof. Bryan Caplan
 Department of Economics  George Mason University
  http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one
 would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not
 
 necessary that anyone but himself should understand it.
 Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*

 --
 Prof. Bryan Caplan
Department of Economics  George Mason University
 http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

   He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one
would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not
necessary that anyone but himself should understand it.
Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*





Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-17 Thread Bryan Caplan
Rodney F Weiher wrote:
 
 Just a note on discount rates.  The late sociologist Ed Banfield had an entire
 theory of poverty, education, crime, and in general, class distinction based
 not on income but on discount rates, e.g. higher rates, less education, more
 crime, lower-class behavior.

Yes, it is a great book that I cite in my recent working paper with
Scott Beaulier.

 It was very intuitive in terms of a lot of observed behavior but I don't
 believe he explained well how how you empirically measure individual discount
 rates
 
 Seems the name of the book was The Unheavenly City. He was influential early
 on in the Nixon administration.
 
 Rodney Weiher
 
 Bryan Caplan wrote:
 
  William Dickens wrote:
  
   As I remember the standard neo-classical answer to this is that the main
   source of endogenaity isn't ability bias but discount rate bias - - that
   people with below average discount rates get more schooling.
 
  I hadn't thought of that (or heard it).  Is there actually any evidence
  on discount rates and educational attainment?  We both know there is a
  lot of evidence on ability (IQ) and educational attainment.
 
  High estimated returns to education are usually claimed to be evidence
  of credit market imperfections.  It seems that the welfare implications
  are quite different if the real problem is high discount rates.
 
   So if the
   question you want to know is the effect of attending high school vs.
   only going through the 11th grade for the average person the return
   appears lower if you don't take into account that the average discount
   rate of people who drop out at 11 is much higher than the average
   discount rate of those who finish high school.
   - - Bill Dickens
  
   William T. Dickens
   The Brookings Institution
   1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
   Washington, DC 20036
   Phone: (202) 797-6113
   FAX: (202) 797-6181
   E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
   AOL IM: wtdickens
  
[EMAIL PROTECTED] 10/16/02 02:13PM 
   I've occasionally heard that instrumental variables (IV) estimators of
   the return to education yield markedly higher estimates than OLS.  Is
   this true?  And how can this make any intuitive sense?  If IV is
   correcting for endogeneity, you would expect things to go the other
   way.
   Why?  With a medical treatment, you would expect endogeneity to
   understate the benefit, because sicker people are more likely to
   voluntarily seek treatment.  But with education, you would expect
   endogeneity to overstate the benefit, because able people are more
   likely to voluntarily enroll.
   --
   Prof. Bryan Caplan
  Department of Economics  George Mason University
   http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
  
 He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one
  would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not
  
  necessary that anyone but himself should understand it.
  Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*
 
  --
  Prof. Bryan Caplan
 Department of Economics  George Mason University
  http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 
He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one
 would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not
 necessary that anyone but himself should understand it.
 Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-17 Thread Bryan Caplan
Alex T Tabarrok wrote:

 Bryan's question, however, can be rephrased as not how do you explain
 the data (low ability bias and high discount rate bias) but why is it
 that ability bias appears low?  

Ability bias isn't really low.  Using the NLSY data, for example,
controlling for AFQT scores reduces the naive estimate of the return to
education from 12.6% to 7.5%.  Ability bias *after* controlling for
intelligence might be low, though.

 In other words aren't there good grounds
 for thinking that ability bias is large?  And if so how is it that this
 doesn't show up in the data?
 
 Alex
 
 --
 Alexander Tabarrok
 Department of Economics, MSN 1D3
 George Mason University
 Fairfax, VA, 22030
 Tel. 703-993-2314
 
 and
 
 Director of Research
 The Independent Institute
 100 Swan Way
 Oakland, CA, 94621
 Tel. 510-632-1366

-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED]

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not 
   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*




Re: Return to Education and IV

2002-10-16 Thread William Dickens

As I remember the standard neo-classical answer to this is that the main
source of endogenaity isn't ability bias but discount rate bias - - that
people with below average discount rates get more schooling.  So if the
question you want to know is the effect of attending high school vs.
only going through the 11th grade for the average person the return
appears lower if you don't take into account that the average discount
rate of people who drop out at 11 is much higher than the average
discount rate of those who finish high school. 
- - Bill Dickens

William T. Dickens
The Brookings Institution
1775 Massachusetts Avenue, NW
Washington, DC 20036
Phone: (202) 797-6113
FAX: (202) 797-6181
E-MAIL: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
AOL IM: wtdickens

 [EMAIL PROTECTED] 10/16/02 02:13PM 
I've occasionally heard that instrumental variables (IV) estimators of
the return to education yield markedly higher estimates than OLS.  Is
this true?  And how can this make any intuitive sense?  If IV is
correcting for endogeneity, you would expect things to go the other
way.  
Why?  With a medical treatment, you would expect endogeneity to
understate the benefit, because sicker people are more likely to
voluntarily seek treatment.  But with education, you would expect
endogeneity to overstate the benefit, because able people are more
likely to voluntarily enroll. 
-- 
Prof. Bryan Caplan
   Department of Economics  George Mason University
http://www.bcaplan.com  [EMAIL PROTECTED] 

  He wrote a letter, but did not post it because he felt that no one 
   would have understood what he wanted to say, and besides it was not

   necessary that anyone but himself should understand it. 
   Leo Tolstoy, *The Cossacks*