Greider's managed trade hypothesis

1998-03-20 Thread Peter Dorman

I'm using Greider's ONE WORLD, READY OR NOT in an interdisciplinary
freshman seminar.  This is my first reading of the book--so far I
generally like it, with reservations.  One question I have concerns
Greider's take on the existing international trade regime.  In chapter 7
he argues that the world trading system does not function in reality the
way it is ususally described.  In general, he says, trade flows are not
market-driven but politically managed.  He seems to lean heavily on
Lawrence Krause, an IR prof at UCSD, who claims that more than half of
all trade is managed in one form or another.  In the Greider-Krause
world, countries (E. Asia, Australia, the US, and Europe) barter market
access for investment, local content, and countertrade quids (?) pro
quo.  This in turn is said to be responsible for a portion of the excess
capacity in global markets, since these political deals are less
responsive to demand constraints than purely market-driven decisions
would be--although Greider makes it clear he believes demand problems
are endemic to capitalism.

My question is, how justified is Greider's view of managed trade in the
existing system?  Is it a small piece of the total or a large, even
determining piece?  Is the WTO just a sham, as he claims it is?  Who
else has written on this topic?

By the way, in case anyone is interested, I have produced a short (2
page) handout to explain Greider's position on oversupply--basically a
very simplified rendering of standard post-keynesianism.  It is written
for students with little economics background, but it assumes loose
familiarity with supply and demand diagrams.  Since it uses a graphic it
can't be included in e-mail but must be sent as an attachment.  It's
formatted in WordPerfect 8.0.  If anyone wants it, they can e-mail me
(not the list!) and I'll pass it along.

Peter Dorman






Class Warfare in the Information Age

1998-03-20 Thread Mark Jones

Michael Perelman's new book, Class Warfare in the Information Age has
come to hand. It fills an important need as a corrective
to the now almost universal Net-hype.

Net-hype ranges a broad spectrum from the pompous (and often vacuous)
theorising of Manuel Castells (Tony Blair's favourite philosopher) --
to the Wired hysterias of Kevin Kelly -- to the imbecile moral panics
(net-crime, net-gambling, net-pedophilia, net-surveillance) which the
mass media manage to mix with uncritical enthusiasm (the Net as the
future of post-human, genetically-enhanced humankind, immortalised in 
virtual worlds; the Net as improbable panacea for Third World poverty; 
the Net facilitating Athenian-style direct democracy; the future as 
a permabulation through virtual malls, etc.) 

Net-hype even extends to Net-Insurrectionaries, Harry Cleaver's espousal 
of sub-comandante's virtual Zap revolution being a prime example.

All this hype needed a god debunking. So it is useful to be reminded, as 
Perelman does, that 'the reality of the information age falls considerably 
short of the futuristic vision of the information age. In fact, the imaginary 
dystopias of science fiction seem to be closer to the truth than the 
fantasies of the champions of the coming information age.'

His critique does not stop there. 

There has been much recent research to suggest that informatics has
not exactly been the productivity boon the corporations had expected.
Nor has labour fared any better: the much-heralded workless society
has coincided with speed-up, longer hours, casualisation and the
three-job anti-social family.

So what is going on? What's behind the hype?

Perelman wants 'to make sense of this welter of conflicting claims and
accusations in the context of the information revolution.'
His conclusions: that the information revolution is 'overblown', that
in any case we are not educating people to make sense of it, that most
new employment is not connected with it, and that its most useful
attribute is to perfect capitalism's command and control. According to
Perelman, what informatics really creates is the Panopticon society,
after Bentham's notion of the perfect prison.

The real subordination of labour to capital is the true name of the
game, even when it comes at the expense of the massive glitches and
crashes which the emphasis on command-and-control instead of decentred
networking often entails.

A major theme of Perelman's book is the privatisation of society's
knowledge-base which, like DNA and even the carbon in the atmosphere,
is one of the last great commons capitalism has left to enclose. What
the information age will bring may actually be a lack of information.
Knowledge will still be power, and access to it will be strictly
controlled. Information will be commoditised, regulated and rendered
much less accessible.

All this will surely be true to some degree, despite the generalised
promise of the Net and of things like Project Gutenberg. Yes, it will
bring an ocean of culture, books, art, knowledge and as bandwidth
grows, moving images, into everyone's lives, as television once did
and movable type before that. But the apparent plethora will conceal a
drastic diminution of opportunity, a reduction in the democracy of
knowledge which robber barons like Dale Carnegie once tried to extend
to the masses. The really important things will be more inaccessible
than ever, shut away behind strong cryptography, archived on orbital
satellites beyond the ken of governments.

Class Warfare in the Information Age is more extended essay that
kilometric, Castells-style exposition. It is portable. But as a tour
d'horizon it's as good as they come. Perelman's strength is that his
overview is historical as well as social.

Frances Yates' great book, The Art of Memory, described how the
invention of alphabets and writing in antiquity, displaced an
attribute of civilised discourse which had taken generations to
develop. It thereby privileged the masses against the leisured class
which had time to develop such skills, expressed in phenomenal 
memory-feats by poets and orators from Homer to Cicero -- and 
even Shakespeare.

Non-coincidentally, these were mostly cultural conservatives. Perelman
reminds of this but his conclusion is not the obvious one that the
Information Age presents similar subversive possibilities to writing.
Conservatives from Plato to TS Eliot were fearful of the consequences
of massifying knowledge, objectifying it and making it available to
the unscrupulous masses. According to Perelman, they would be less
fearful of the 'information revolution' which may have the opposite
effect, making knowledge (as opposed to information) less accessible,
reinforcing authority and hierarchy.

The meat of Perelman's extended essay is his discussion of corporate
strategies for privatising the gold in people's minds. Quoting Kenneth
Arrow: 'embedded information... [as] capital depends on slow mobility
of information-rich labor', he 

Re: Griliches Poverty

1998-03-20 Thread Jay Hecht

In a message dated 98-03-19 11:52:19 EST, you write:

 
 Eh? Where'd this happen? Which Fed economist, where?
  
Latest issue of the "Journal of Economic Perspectives."

jason





further progress in econonmics

1998-03-20 Thread Doug Henwood

 "A Microeconomic Analysis of Slavery in Comparison to Free
  Labor Economies"

  BY: HALUK I. ERGIN
Bilkent University
  SERDAR SAYAN
Bilkent University


 SSRN ELECTRONIC DOCUMENT DELIVERY:
 http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=62685

  Paper ID: Bilkent University Dept. of Economics WP 97-08
  Date: July 1997

  Contact:  Serdar Sayan
  E-Mail:   MAILTO:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Postal:   Bilkent University, Department of Economics,
06533 Ankara, Turkey
  Phone:+90(312)266-4000  Ext. 2071
  Fax:  +90(312)266-5140
  Co-Auth:  MAILTO:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  ERN Ref:  LABOR:WPS98-118

 In addition to supervision costs, the labor cost of an
 enterprise (plantation) in the system of slavery consists of
 the cost of acquiring the slaves and the subsistence
 compensation given out to the slaves. In this paper, we leave
 aside the issue of supervision costs previously taken up in
 the theoretical literature on slavery and focus on these two
 peculiar components of labor costs. We analyze the
 implications of this cost structure on the levels of
 profitability, efficiency and determination of equilibrium
 wages, and compare them to systems with free labor markets,
 along a continuum of demand-side Cournotic competition. For
 this purpose, we first use a model characterized by a
 decreasing returns to scale technology and show, parallel to
 the findings of Vedder, et. al. (1990), that the equilibrium
 subsistence wage in the system of slavery is strictly lower
 than the marginal product of labor. We then extend the model,
 given the same technology and preferences, to free labor
 markets covering possibilities ranging from monopsony to
 perfect competition in the limit and obtain a second and
 perhaps more striking result: Differently from equilibria in
 imperfectly competitive free labor markets, slavery and
 perfect competition equilibria are Pareto optimal.
 Furthermore, our comparisons across labor market scenarios
 suggest that the resistance of slaveholders to the
 abolishment of slavery is directly related to the expected
 level of demand-side competition in the free labor market
 which would replace slavery. Finally, we show that the
 conclusions derived from our analysis would remain generally
 valid under a constant returns to scale technology as well.

 JEL Classification: N31, J31, P51, J42, L13







Re: Section 7(a)

1998-03-20 Thread Michael Perelman

Paul asked why the state should be frightened.  he said


 (we're talking 1932 and early 1993, I guess)

Capitalism was discredited at the time.  The whole class configuration had
shifted.  The state certainly could not blame the economic disorder on the
unions at the time.

--
Michael Perelman
Economics Department
California State University
Chico, CA 95929

Tel. 916-898-5321
E-Mail [EMAIL PROTECTED]







[Fwd: Crime and Punishment 1999 (fwd)]

1998-03-20 Thread Michael Perelman



Sid Shniad wrote:

  H. Bruce Franklin review in the Guardian Weekly:
  CRIME AND PUNISHMENT IN AMERICA By Elliott Currie
  Holt/Metropolitan. 230pp. US$23
 
  THIS IS a very unfashionable book.  Elliott Currie does not believe that
  we need to build more and more prisons,  impose longer sentences, make
  prisons as harsh as possible, eliminate  educational opportunities for
  prisoners, reinstitute chain gangs, treat  juvenile offenders as adults,
  and divert still more funds from social  services to penal institutions.
  He clings to the old-fashioned notion that  we should concentrate more on
  the prevention of crime. He even goes so far  as to accept the hopelessly
  outdated idea that widespread poverty is the  main cause of violent
  crime. If all this were not antiquated enough,  Currie also evidently
  assumes that rational argument based on scientific  knowledge -- i.e.
  reason and facts -- can change social policy. Even his  prose style is
  anachronistic: earnest, free of jargon, lucid.
 
When Currie, who has taught sociology and criminology at Yale and
  Berkeley,  advanced similar arguments in his 1985 volume Confronting
  Crime, the New York Times reviewer noted that the "biggest incarceration
  binge in merican history" had increased the nation's prison population
  from fewer than 200,000 in 1970 to 454,000 by 1984. What may have seemed
  an astonishing number of inmates back in 1984 is dwarfed by the current
  prison population of 1.2 million, plus an additional half-a-million
  people in local jails.
 
  The United States now has by far the largest prison system on the planet.
  There are more prisoners in California alone than in any other country
  in the world except China and Russia. The present U.S. rate of
  incarceration is  six times the global average, seven times that of
  Europe, 14 times that  of Japan, 23 times that of India. European rates
  of incarceration are  consistently well below 100 per 100,000 population;
  the rate of incarceration  of African-American males is close to 4,000 per
  100,000.
 
  As Currie puts it  in the present volume, "mass incarceration has been
  the most thoroughly  implemented government social program of our time,"
  and we have thus been  conducting a gigantic social "experiment,"
  "testing the degree to  which a modern industrial society can maintain
  public order through the threat of punishment."
 
   Has this experiment worked? Media attention has recently highlighted the
  falling rate of crime for the past four years. As Currie demonstrates,
  this decline has come during a period of unusually low unemployment and
  relative prosperity, actually bolstering his thesis that extreme poverty
  is the main cause of crime. Moreover, he notes that the crime rate has
  been falling only in relation to the extremely high levels of 1990-93.
 
  If we compare 1996 with 1984, the year cited in the review of Currie's
  earlier volume, we discover that the crime rate (according to the FBI's
  annual Crime Index) has actually risen 13 percent. The costs of this
  social experiment are immense. As Currie points out, the money spent on
  prisons has been "taken from the parts of the public sector that
  educate, train, socialize, treat, nurture, and house the population --
  particularly the children of the poor." Currie if anything understates
  the consequences elsewhere in the public sector. For example, California
  now spends more on prisons than on higher education. Crime And Punishment
  In America cogently debunks what Currie labels the "myths" that rationalize
  and legitimize the prison craze.
 
  The "myth of leniency" (the prevailing notion that criminals are being let
  off too easily or let out too soon) is shown to be based on phony
  statistics, "unless we believe that . . . everyone convicted of an offense
  -- no matter how minor -- should be sent to jail or prison, and that all
  of those sent to prison should stay there for the rest of their lives."
  The "myth" that "prison works" ignores the soaring crime rates during most
  of the quarter-century of the incarceration experiment; it also assumes
  that the only alternative available to us has been doing nothing at all
  about crime.
 
  This leads to the parts of the book dearest to the author's heart:
  alternatives to mass incarceration. With thorough documentation from
  recent research, Currie describes a number of social programs that have
  indeed dramatically reduced rates of crime or recidivism, even among
  groups of people generally considered beyond hope. Examples he gives
  range from prenatal and preschool home visitation targeting child abuse
  through enriched schools for high-risk teenagers to successful community
  programs for youths who already have multiple arrests. The modest costs
  of these programs, together with their tangible benefits, offer a stark
  contrast to the enormously expensive mass incarceration model, with all
  its attendant 

Re: Section 7(a)

1998-03-20 Thread Ellen Dannin [EMAIL PROTECTED]

There are a few sources for information on these events that have not
so far been mentioned.

James Gross (Cornell labor historian) has written a multi-volume history
of the NLRA and NLRB.

Jim Pope (Rutgers Law school) is currently doing an analysis of s.7(a).

And related but slightly off topic:

Daniel Ernst (Georgetown law / history) wrote Lawyers Against Labor about
two years ago. It looks at influences on the drafting of the NLRA.

Another who has written recently on this era include Thomas Kohler at
Boston College Law School.

Jack Getman (Texas Law School) has what should be a very interesting book
coming out through Cornell called The Betrayal of Local 14 -- about the
Paperworkers strike at Jay, Maine.

Ellen J. Dannin
California Western School of Law
225 Cedar Street
San Diego, CA  92101
Phone:  619-525-1449
Fax:619-696-






Re: what's in a name?

1998-03-20 Thread boddhisatva





To whom...,




Mr. Sokolowski's post illustrates the misconception that socialism
and a command economy are anything like the same animal.  If socialism was a
command economy, then it would be true that the difference between socialism
and capitalism was a matter of degree.  Therefore, Marxists can happily
conclude that socialism is *not* characterized by the presence of a command
economy.  Instead, it is a question of ownership.  When ownership is
constituted in a capitalist way, we have capitalism.  If ownership was ever
to be constituted in a socialist way, we would have socialism.  Fortunately
for young socialists, ownership has never been constituted this way, and thus
the putative "socialist" regimes of the past need not be a millstone around
their necks.  



There, that ought to finish *that* debate.  :)





peace







RE: [Fwd: Crime and Punishment 1999 (fwd)]

1998-03-20 Thread Fellows, Jeffrey

Thank you for the reference Michael. I am organizing a long-term project
roughly called "the economic causes and consequences of violence: a
public health approach."  The book will examine the public health issues
of family and intimate partner violence, youth violence, and suicide,
from a similar point of view.  It will include sections on the economic
causes (influences) of violence, the economic costs of violence, and the
potential impact of violence prevention programs. I am currently working
on narrower aspects of this subject, i.e., filling in the pieces.

The criminal justice approach focuses on legally-defined crimal acts.
The public health approach uses more of an episode-of-illness (or
injury) classification. This can be a very important  distinction
(especially to Marxists) when you have categories of violence not
defined as a crime.

Jeff
 --
From: Michael Perelman
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: [Fwd: Crime and Punishment 1999 (fwd)]
Date: Friday, March 20, 1998 12:02PM



Sid Shniad wrote:

  H. Bruce Franklin review in the Guardian Weekly:
  CRIME AND PUNISHMENT IN AMERICA By Elliott Currie
  Holt/Metropolitan. 230pp. US$23
 
  THIS IS a very unfashionable book.  Elliott Currie does not believe
that
  we need to build more and more prisons,  impose longer sentences,
make
  prisons as harsh as possible, eliminate  educational opportunities
for
  prisoners, reinstitute chain gangs, treat  juvenile offenders as
adults,
  and divert still more funds from social  services to penal
institutions.
  He clings to the old-fashioned notion that  we should concentrate
more on
  the prevention of crime. He even goes so far  as to accept the
hopelessly
  outdated idea that widespread poverty is the  main cause of violent
  crime. If all this were not antiquated enough,  Currie also
evidently
  assumes that rational argument based on scientific  knowledge --
i.e.
  reason and facts -- can change social policy. Even his  prose style
is
  anachronistic: earnest, free of jargon, lucid.
 
When Currie, who has taught sociology and criminology at Yale and
  Berkeley,  advanced similar arguments in his 1985 volume Confronting
  Crime, the New York Times reviewer noted that the "biggest
incarceration
  binge in merican history" had increased the nation's prison
population
  from fewer than 200,000 in 1970 to 454,000 by 1984. What may have
seemed
  an astonishing number of inmates back in 1984 is dwarfed by the
current
  prison population of 1.2 million, plus an additional half-a-million
  people in local jails.
 
  The United States now has by far the largest prison system on the
planet.
  There are more prisoners in California alone than in any other
country
  in the world except China and Russia. The present U.S. rate of
  incarceration is  six times the global average, seven times that of
  Europe, 14 times that  of Japan, 23 times that of India. European
rates
  of incarceration are  consistently well below 100 per 100,000
population;
  the rate of incarceration  of African-American males is close to
4,000 per
  100,000.
 
  As Currie puts it  in the present volume, "mass incarceration has
been
  the most thoroughly  implemented government social program of our
time,"
  and we have thus been  conducting a gigantic social "experiment,"
  "testing the degree to  which a modern industrial society can
maintain
  public order through the threat of punishment."
 
   Has this experiment worked? Media attention has recently
highlighted the
  falling rate of crime for the past four years. As Currie
demonstrates,
  this decline has come during a period of unusually low unemployment
and
  relative prosperity, actually bolstering his thesis that extreme
poverty
  is the main cause of crime. Moreover, he notes that the crime rate
has
  been falling only in relation to the extremely high levels of
1990-93.
 
  If we compare 1996 with 1984, the year cited in the review of
Currie's
  earlier volume, we discover that the crime rate (according to the
FBI's
  annual Crime Index) has actually risen 13 percent. The costs of this
  social experiment are immense. As Currie points out, the money spent
on
  prisons has been "taken from the parts of the public sector that
  educate, train, socialize, treat, nurture, and house the population
--
  particularly the children of the poor." Currie if anything
understates
  the consequences elsewhere in the public sector. For example,
California
  now spends more on prisons than on higher education. Crime And
Punishment
  In America cogently debunks what Currie labels the "myths" that
rationalize
  and legitimize the prison craze.
 
  The "myth of leniency" (the prevailing notion that criminals are
being let
  off too easily or let out too soon) is shown to be based on phony
  statistics, "unless we believe that . . . everyone convicted of an
offense
  -- no matter how minor -- should be sent to jail or prison, and that
all
  of those sent to prison should stay there for the rest 

Re: a proposed leading indicator -Reply

1998-03-20 Thread Louis Proyect

Tim Stroshane:
How about the number of estimated homeless population per 1,000
resident population?  Another indicator could perhaps include the
percent of households in America paying 50 percent of their
income in rent, then the percent of households at or below 50
percent of their regional median incomes who pay 50 percent of
their incomes in rent.  It would be interesting to gauge how the
poor fair relative to the middle class in that regard, and over
time.

Related to this is the question of the number of people living in
apartments, those who are not homeless but who are miserably crowded. The
NY Times ran articles last year about the horrible problems facing Mexican
and other immigrants who are crammed 10 to a one-bedroom apartment in
sections of Queens or the Bronx. Contagious illnesses like TB, fires, and
psychological stress make these places hell.

Louis Proyect






Re: further progress in econonmics

1998-03-20 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

At 11:40 AM 3/20/98 -0500, Doug Henwood wrote:
 "A Microeconomic Analysis of Slavery in Comparison to Free
  Labor Economies"


---snip

Aside the econo-babble mumbo-jumbo, the argument is hardly original.  Cf:
Witold Kula, _An Economic Theory of the Feudal System_, London: NLB, 1976
who essentially argues that the profitablity of the fedual plantation
(using Eastern European data) was obtained by the fact that the product was
sold on competitive (Western) markets, wheres the Eastern institution of
serfdom limited labour mobility resulting in its local oversupply, thus
reducing its "marginal value" (as comparted to the market systems of
Western Europe). To my knowledge, the original proponent of that argument
in the 1930s was the Russian economist  A.V. Chayanov (A Theory of Peasant
Economy ? published in English by Wisconsin U Press if I remember
correctly) who reached the same conslusion by analyzing emprical data from
the tsarist Russia.

The advantage of the cited approaches is that they are emprical science not
an exercise in masturbatory... err mathematical abstraction.


Regards,






  BY: HALUK I. ERGIN
Bilkent University
  SERDAR SAYAN
Bilkent University


 SSRN ELECTRONIC DOCUMENT DELIVERY:
 http://papers.ssrn.com/paper.taf?abstract_id=62685

  Paper ID: Bilkent University Dept. of Economics WP 97-08
  Date: July 1997

  Contact:  Serdar Sayan
  E-Mail:   MAILTO:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  Postal:   Bilkent University, Department of Economics,
06533 Ankara, Turkey
  Phone:+90(312)266-4000  Ext. 2071
  Fax:  +90(312)266-5140
  Co-Auth:  MAILTO:[EMAIL PROTECTED]
  ERN Ref:  LABOR:WPS98-118

 In addition to supervision costs, the labor cost of an
 enterprise (plantation) in the system of slavery consists of
 the cost of acquiring the slaves and the subsistence
 compensation given out to the slaves. In this paper, we leave
 aside the issue of supervision costs previously taken up in
 the theoretical literature on slavery and focus on these two
 peculiar components of labor costs. We analyze the
 implications of this cost structure on the levels of
 profitability, efficiency and determination of equilibrium
 wages, and compare them to systems with free labor markets,
 along a continuum of demand-side Cournotic competition. For
 this purpose, we first use a model characterized by a
 decreasing returns to scale technology and show, parallel to
 the findings of Vedder, et. al. (1990), that the equilibrium
 subsistence wage in the system of slavery is strictly lower
 than the marginal product of labor. We then extend the model,
 given the same technology and preferences, to free labor
 markets covering possibilities ranging from monopsony to
 perfect competition in the limit and obtain a second and
 perhaps more striking result: Differently from equilibria in
 imperfectly competitive free labor markets, slavery and
 perfect competition equilibria are Pareto optimal.
 Furthermore, our comparisons across labor market scenarios
 suggest that the resistance of slaveholders to the
 abolishment of slavery is directly related to the expected
 level of demand-side competition in the free labor market
 which would replace slavery. Finally, we show that the
 conclusions derived from our analysis would remain generally
 valid under a constant returns to scale technology as well.

 JEL Classification: N31, J31, P51, J42, L13



Wojtek Sokolowski 
Institute for Policy Studies
Johns Hopkins University
Baltimore, MD 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233

Opinions expressed above are those of this writer only.  They do not
represent the views or policies of the Institute for Policy Studies, the
Johns Hopkins University, or anyone else affiliated with these institutions.








Re: ASSA session cuts

1998-03-20 Thread Rosser Jr, John Barkley

 The letter went to John J. Siegfried, Secretary of the 
AEA.  He is at Vanderbilt University in the Economics 
Department.  His email (that's how I sent mine) is 
[EMAIL PROTECTED]  I'm sure he'll be 
overjoyed that I've handed it out, :-).
 This strikes me as being the time to make appeals, 
efforts, etc.  They may have locked themselves in for this 
year, but maybe it can be cut back for the future.
Barkley Rosser
On Thu, 19 Mar 1998 21:11:45 -0500 Colin Danby 
[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 Barkley:  
 
 Great letter.  Is there any value in having more of us 
 unwashed types write in support?  If so can you post a 
 name and address to write to?  
 
 Thanks, Colin
 
 PS If AEA is busily stifling us hets is there any good 
 reason to remain a member?  I could easily manage 
 without my own copies of its ubiquitous ( iniquitous) 
 journals.
 

-- 
Rosser Jr, John Barkley
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







Re: a proposed leading indicator

1998-03-20 Thread Mark Jones

Sperm counts.

Doug Henwood wrote:

 Speaking of indicators, The Nation has asked me to put together a set of
 economic/social indicators, to be published quarterly, that would be
 revealing, interesting, and against the grain of conventional thinking.

 Any suggestions?

 Doug








Wall Street workers' paradise

1998-03-20 Thread valis

Date: Sat, 17 Jan 1998 20:24:33 -0600
...
Newsgroups: alt.revolution.counter
Subject: Capitalism under Vaclav Havel

Here's a description of conditions under 'free market'
capitalism in the Czech Republic, as created under the
counter-revolutionary leadership of the celebrated
Vaclav Havel:


   "Havel's 'democratic reforms' have brought cuts in
health care, public housing, and education; and reductions
in rent and fuel subsidies to low income people.  The
condition of labor has drastically declined.  Sick leave,
maternity leave, paid vacations, and other job benefits
once taken for granted under communism have been cut
or abolished.  Worker sanitariums, vacation resorts,
health clinics, sports and cultural centers, daycare centers,
and other features that made communist enterprises
more than just workplaces, have nearly vanished.
Hospitals, libraries, houses of culture, and public transport
systems are closing or services have drastically declined.
Rest homes formerly reserved for workers have been
privatized and redone as casinos, night clubs, and
restaurants for the nouveaux riches.
  Real income has shrunk by as much as 30 percent under
Havel's free market rule.  More than one-third of citizens
live in abject poverty and large numbers hold two or
more jobs and work up to 14 hours a day.  Those who
have suffered the most are among the more vulnerable:
women, children, the elderly, and ordinary workers and
peasants.
   There is an upsurge in official corruption and organized
crime, as well as in street crime, murder, homelessness,
drug addiction, mental and physical illness, and suicide.
Women are being recruited in unprecedented numbers
for the booming sex industry that caters to foreign and
domestic businessmen.  Unable to find employment in
their fields, many highly educated women go abroad to
work as prostitutes.  Children are also channeled into
the sex market.  'Prague and Budapest now rival Bangkok
and Manila as hubs for the collection of children to
serve visiting pedophiles.'
   Oddly, the Prague police force today under Havel's
free market "democracy" is many times larger than it was
under the 'communist police state,' when 'relatively few
police were needed.'"


This is an excerpt from the article, "Vaclav Havel's Warm
and Fuzzy Image," by Michael Parenti in COVERT
ACTION QUARTERLY, Fall 1997, p. 47.










Re: what's in a name?

1998-03-20 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

At 02:44 PM 3/20/98 -0500, Rakesh Bhandari wrote:

Yes,it is one thing to study motion in a vacuum and then to determine the
modification of motion by air pressure or viscosity. So Marx may have
initially assumed a closed capitalist society, without foreign trade or
vestigal or intermediate classes.

Let us assume a closed national capitalist economy (which may not be Marx's
assumption). If the current stock of machinery or inventories of such
machinery  has suffered moral depreciation, this may represent a
destruction of value in an enclosed national capitalism. However if such
morally depreciated machinery can be sold *above value* either through
foreign direct investment (with most of the financing being domestic) or
through licensing agreements (according to Mansfield, et al 1982, the
average age of technologies transferred to their developing economy
subsidiaries by US firms during the 1960-1978 period was ten years and 13
years of technologies transferred through licensing; Mowery estimates
imports of capital equipment embody technologies that lies somewhere
between the age of those avaialbe through licensign and those transferred
to wholly-owned subsidiaries), then falling profitability on past
investments engendered by moral depreciation no longer obtains in an open
system. What may rather come to pass is the perenial debt of those who have
used loans to purchase equipment which is economically obsolescent in world
market terms.

But such modifications to capital's dynamics may not always be important.
To the extent that the dynamic of capital itself implies the destruction of
vestigal or intermediate classes, then capital's own development renders
less effective such interference to its own laws of motion.


That is an intersting example indeed.  It makes me wonder, what does it
take for ther market system to be 'open'.  The initial intuition tells
"possibility of geographical or lateral expansion."  But then, of course,
we witness the expanasion into different areas of social activity, first by
expanding into new social groups (e.g. the 'marketisation' of the women's
work, like child care, or the newest yuppie trend 'subsitute' mothering),
and second bly planned obsolescence.  The compuer industry gives the latter
infinite possibilities, all t\waht it takes a perfectly usable product
'obsolete' is changing a few codes.

But that is not the latest word.  The trading in "futures" may be
intepreted as expanding the existing markets diachronically or vertically
in time.  How far can that go, Doug Henwood? 

But if those speculations are correct, that means that capital will always
find new reserves for expansion, and that is really bad news for the
prediction of capitalism collapsing under the burden of its own
contradictions.

regards,




Wojtek Sokolowski 
Institute for Policy Studies
Johns Hopkins University
Baltimore, MD 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233

Opinions expressed above are those of this writer only.  They do not
represent the views or policies of the Institute for Policy Studies, the
Johns Hopkins University, or anyone else affiliated with these institutions.








Re: US real earnings boom

1998-03-20 Thread James Devine

At 05:00 PM 3/20/98 -0500, Doug wrote:
Between Feb 97 and Feb 98, U.S. real hourly earnings for all private sector
workers were up 2.7%, led by 3.0% gain in services; manufacturing lagged at
up 1.6%. ...
Is this a blip, shortly to be squashed by Alan Greenspan, or a real
reversal of the downtrend in real hourly earnings that began in 1973?

A few weeks ago, the author of the weekly economic outlook pages of
BUSINESS WEEK interpreted a statement by Greenspan as saying "if the East
Asian crisis doesn't slow the US economy, then I'll do it."

in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/1997F/ECON/jdevine.html
"It takes a busload of faith to get by." -- Lou Reed.






Re: [Fwd: Crime and Punishment 1999 (fwd)]

1998-03-20 Thread Thomas Kruse

A weensy complement to:

When Currie, who has taught sociology and criminology at Yale and
  Berkeley,  advanced similar arguments in his 1985 volume Confronting
  Crime, the New York Times reviewer noted that the "biggest incarceration
  binge in merican history" had increased the nation's prison population
  from fewer than 200,000 in 1970 to 454,000 by 1984. What may have seemed
  an astonishing number of inmates back in 1984 is dwarfed by the current
  prison population of 1.2 million, plus an additional half-a-million
  people in local jails.


   Fed. Prisons   Drug
Year   Pop.Offenders %
-
1980 24,363   6,12025.1%
1982 29,673   7,92026.7%
1984 34,263  10,11029.5%
1986 44,408  16,34036.8%
1988 49,928  22,27044.6%
1990 65,526  35,06053.5%
1992 80,259  47,27058.9%
1994 95,034  58,26061.3%
Grwth:390%952%

In the same period federal anti-drug spending grew from 2.7 billion in 1985
to over 15 billion in 1997.

Tom Kruse / Casilla 5812 / Cochabamba, Bolivia
Tel/Fax: (591-42) 48242
Email: [EMAIL PROTECTED]






Re: [Fwd: Crime and Punishment 1999 (fwd)

1998-03-20 Thread Tim Stroshane

What is the source on Thomas Kruse's drug offenders prison
population data?





Globalization: Fed Reserve Bank View; Here Comes SAFTA

1998-03-20 Thread Michael Eisenscher

Globalization and Its Effects on the U.S. Economy By Edward G. Boehne,
President, Federal Reserve
Bank of Philadelphia at the World Affairs Council Of Greater Valley Forge 
01:00 p.m Mar 20, 1998 Eastern 

PAOLI, Pa., March 20 /PRNewswire/ -- The following is the text of a speech
given by Edward G. Boehne, President, Federal
Reserve Bank of Philadelphia at the World Affairs Council of Greater Valley
Forge: 

The Outlook 

We have been experiencing remarkably good economic performance. This
economic expansion is now in its eighth straight
year. With rapid economic growth for several years, the unemployment rate
has fallen to near 4-1/2 percent, its lowest
level in nearly a quarter of a century. Last year more than 3 million new
jobs were created. And all of this was
accomplished without a resurgence in inflation. In fact, consumer price
inflation slowed to a little less than 2 percent in
1997, after rising more than 3 percent in 1996. 

Last year's slowing inflation came as something of a surprise to economic
forecasters. With demand for goods and
services growing rapidly at a time when the unemployment rate is lower than
it has been in decades, wages are rising
more rapidly. Forecasters thought that pressure on wages would translate
into bigger price increases. Indeed, a year ago
the major risk facing the US economy was that too rapid growth in demand
would lead to overheating and rising inflation.
But businesses continue to find ways to improve productivity and keep their
unit labor costs down. Businesses also
continue to expand their capacity at a rapid clip, with the result that
capacity utilization rates in industry are now
generally lower than they were three years ago. Faster productivity growth
and enlarged industrial capacity both
contribute to keeping inflation down. So does a strong dollar and the
intense competition that American firms face from
their foreign rivals. 

This year the risks facing the economy are less one-sided than they were a
year ago. Today, there is less concern that
overheating will occur. In fact, downside risks loom much larger now than
they have for the past two years. And as
testimony to the growing globalization of our economy, the concern about
downside risks to our nation's economy stems
not so much from domestic developments, but from international ones. 

Although there are downside risks, my judgment is that the U.S. economy will
continue to grow at a healthy pace.
Developments in Asia will mean slower growth of U.S. exports and a rising
U.S. trade deficit, but those factors will only
partly offset the momentum in consumer spending and business fixed
investment. The net result is likely to be more
moderate growth than in 1997. 

Globalization 

More generally, the effects of globalization on the U.S. economy go well
beyond the issue of Asia's effects on the US
economy this year. The effects of globalization are going to be more
far-reaching and more permanent. 

"Globalization" means different things to different people, so let me begin
by giving you my definition: Globalization is the
process of moving toward a world in which we produce, distribute, sell,
finance, and invest without regard to national
boundaries. 

Are we in a world in which national boundaries are irrelevant? No, and we
won't be anytime soon. But we have been moving
in that direction, and we will continue to do so. A German company
manufactures cars in Mexico for sale in the United
States. Japanese consumers calling a US mail order company to buy sweaters
made in Scotland may find themselves
talking to telephone operators in Ireland. And portfolio managers in the
Hong Kong offices of New York financial firms buy
and sell Korean stocks on behalf of British as well as American investors.
Globalization, in the sense that I am using it, is
driven by reductions in trade barriers and capital controls, by attempts to
capture economies of scale, and by dramatic
quality improvements and cost reductions in long-distance communications. 

While many people fear globalization, the process is not fundamentally
different from the relocation of manufacturing and
the integration of financial markets that occurred within the US in the 20th
century. We know that manufacturing plants
and jobs moved from the Northeast to the South and Southwest. At the same
time, companies established nationwide
distribution systems and nationwide brands. Now a company headquartered in
Pennsylvania may have production
facilities in 6 states, buy inputs produced in 12 states, and sell goods in
all 50 states. 

Similarly, all but the largest Pennsylvania companies used to rely on local
banks for the bulk of their financing. Now they
borrow not only from local banks but also from a variety of financial firms
headquartered in other parts of the country.
And residents of Pennsylvania, who used to keep their savings on deposit at
local banks, now entrust much of their wealth
to portfolio managers in New York who buy stocks and bonds 

SA8000: New Global Standards of Social Accountability

1998-03-20 Thread Michael Eisenscher

[What follows was passed along by Tim Lavery.   Both labor and international
solidarity activists may find it worth a read.  I assume, though he provides
no indication, that this article has a copyright held by Quality Digest.  I
have no further information regarding the periodical, date of publication,
etc.  Contact them directly if you want permission to use it.  (Tim may be
able to provide contact information.)  Apologies for duplicates as a
consequence of cross-posting.]

Michael, below is an article from Quality Digest which explains the
issue.  Think you might find it interesting.

Regards,

Tim

As most quality professionals know, quality products usually aren't
produced in conditions where workers are unhappy. Long
hours, unsafe working conditions, unfair wages, discrimination and
arduous labor can create work environments where quality and employee
satisfaction prove rare.

However, ensuring fair treatment of employees in today's complex 
business  environment can seem as daunting as it was a
century ago. Numerous stakeholders -- suppliers, manufacturers,
buying agents, contractors and subcontractors -- share the
responsibility of safeguarding worker rights, but sometimes the efforts of these
various groups fall short for any number of reasons. The problem may lie in
greed
and cruelty, as it has so often in the past, or it may stem from
something else, such as entrenched cultural differences.

To address and, hopefully, eliminate unfair and
inhumane labor practices, Social Accountability 8000, a new international and
inter-industry standard, has been created. Based on ISO 9000, SA8000
targets workplace conditions in factories around the world. The
standard was written by an advisory board of 25 people, including
representatives from the Council on Economic Priorities Accreditation
Agency, Amnesty International, the National Child Labor Committee,
KPMG, SGS International Certification Services, Avon Products,
Toys R Us, Reebok, The Body Shop, clothing company Eileen Fisher,
Amalgamated Bank and the International Textile Workers Union.

The difference between SA8000 and its cousins ISO 9000
and ISO 14000 is that this new standard includes performance
requirements in addition to system requirements. SA8000 requires that
employers pay wages sufficient to meet workers' basic needs, provide
a safe working environment, not employ child or forced labor, and not
require employees to regularly work longer than 48 hours per
week.

"One of the problems in monitoring working conditions
or human rights has been to move beyond the anecdotal," emphasizes
Eileen Kohl Kaufman, program director for the Council on Economic
Priorities Accreditation Agency. "It's very hard to have any sense
of what conditions were like last week or have any confidence
in what they will be like next week. We felt that by merging the
performance audit with a quality systems concept, we'd be able to provide a
system that could give more confidence and more comparability, both across
industries and across countries."

Many companies have developed codes of conduct that
promote basic rights and prohibit such practices as child labor,
prison labor and discrimination. As a result, hundreds of codes now
exist, a situation that not only poses difficulties for suppliers but is
extremely inefficient. "The effort to combat serious violations of workers'
rights
is thus hampered both by a lack of clear definitions of terms and by a
lack of consensus on the basic benchmarks in codes themselves," states
CEPAA's framework for the standard.

Kaufman agrees. "It's difficult for the people from the customer 
companies who are responsible for monitoring the code
of conduct as well as vouching for working conditions," she observes.
"It's overwhelming."

SA8000's certification process will resemble that of ISO 9000; 
accrediting certification firms to the standard began
in late January. The standard will require certification bodies to educate
themselves about the facilities they certify and the regions where those
facilities are located. If a registrar wants to certify a facility, it must
develop
a process for auditing the facility's compliance to the standard. Potential
SA8000-accredited registrars include BVQI, ITS Intertek Services, SGS-ICS
and ACTS Testing Services.

SA8000 requirements

The standard has four major sections; the fourth,
titled "Social Accountability Requirements," includes nine subsections
that cover such topics as child labor, forced labor, health and safety,
freedom of association and right to collective bargaining,
discrimination, disciplinary practices, working hours, compensation and 
management systems.

Any organization wishing to subscribe to the standard
must not engage in or support child labor, which SA8000 specifies as any
work by a child younger than 15 years of age (or, in special cases, age
14, in accordance with developing-country exceptions under ILO Convention
138). Nor is forced labor -- defined in the standard as 

Chase Manhattan responds

1998-03-20 Thread PHILLPS

The Chase Manhattan response boggles the mind as Wojtek
has noted.  On reflection I have some advice to Doug that,
rather than annex Canada (which has been the US response
for over a century to the upstart pretentions that some
other people on this continent have that they might
prefer some other, more humane and democratic system
than that in our neighbour to the south), all he really
needs to do is take out a membership in a Canadian credit
union, have his cheques deposited there, and then withdraw
his money through a Credit Union (bank) card.  You get the
current exchange rate with only a 1 or 2 dollar service
charge.  And you can actually use your credit union card
at the local bank machine of the Chase Manhattan bank!

Oh, and about the annexation of Canada.  I should note that
the US citizens of the NorthWest Angle of the US on lake
of the Woods are petitioning congress to secede and join
Canada because of the rotten treatment they are getting
from the US.  I just hope the US Government gives them the
same support in their seccession movement as it gives to
the Kosovo terrorists.

Paul Phillips,
Economics,
University of Manitoba.





Re: what's in a name?

1998-03-20 Thread James Devine

Wojtek wrote: 
It is one thing to say that Marxist theory explains some important aspects
of capitalist relations  of production (which I think it does), quite a
differnt thing to determine to what degree those capitalist relations of
production ar implemented in actual societies and to what extent they are
mitigated by historical contingencies,

Rakesh replied:
Yes,it is one thing to study motion in a vacuum and then to determine the
modification of motion by air pressure or viscosity. So Marx may have
initially assumed a closed capitalist society, without foreign trade or
vestigal or intermediate classes.

It's interesting how different Marx's perspective is on foreign trade
compared to the mainstream view, even if the theoretical impact is similar.
Instead of simplifying matters by assuming a closed economy (as US
economists are wont to do, or were wont to do until recent decades), Marx
treats "the whole world as one nation" in which "capitalist production is
everywhere established... in every branch of industry" [CAPITAL, vol. I,
Int'l Publ. paperback, 581n]. This assumption is weakened a bit in vol. III. 

On the other hand, he argues that "vestigial" classes would be swept away
by capitalism, by absorbing them into capitalism. Though he seems to have
seen them coming, he didn't analyze the intermediate classes generated by
capitalism's own development very much -- hardly enough to be satisfying.
The new middle classes might be treated as sharing characteristics with
both the capitalists and the workers, at least on a very abstract level.

I think the main simplication of CAPITAL is that there Marx assumes away
the independent dynamics of working-class movements. The book is about
capital's dynamics largely holding working class organization constant
(holding the cultural-historical level of subsistence constant, for
example), mostly dealing with workers' _reactions_ to the lengthening of
the working day or the speed-up imposed by the capitalist use of machinery.
The book doesn't talk about the development of working class organization
toward (or away from) forming clear class consciousness, political parties,
and the like (counter-hegemony). But Marx talks about this elsewhere, in
other writings. See Mike Lebowitz' book, BEYOND CAPITAL. Bringing in the
political economy of the working class -- to complement Marx's political
economy of capital -- seems an absolutely necessary component of any effort
to understand capitalist dynamics.

For example, the relatively high standard of living of US (white male)
workers in the 1950s and 1960s resulted from the victories in struggles of
the 1930s and 1940s, combined with a relatively good situation for
deepening or defending those victories during the 1950s and 1960s
(relatively strong labor-power demand, limited capital mobility). This high
living standard was fought all the way by capital, but it's only in the
1980s and 1990s that capital is winning full-scale (with obvious exceptions
like the UPS strike). To try to understand all of this simply by looking at
the dynamics of capital is to miss a lot. 

in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine  [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/1997F/ECON/jdevine.html
"Segui il tuo corso, e lascia dir le genti." (Go your own way and let
people talk.) -- K. Marx, paraphrasing Dante A.






US real earnings boom

1998-03-20 Thread Doug Henwood

Between Feb 97 and Feb 98, U.S. real hourly earnings for all private sector
workers were up 2.7%, led by 3.0% gain in services; manufacturing lagged at
up 1.6%. There's been a steady acceleration in real wage growth since it
turned up in mid-1995, with a spurt over the last year; just a year ago,
the overall gain was under 1%.

Is this a blip, shortly to be squashed by Alan Greenspan, or a real
reversal of the downtrend in real hourly earnings that began in 1973?

Doug







Re: Chase Manhattan responds

1998-03-20 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

At 03:52 PM 3/20/98 -0500,  boddhisatva quoted Chase Manhattan:

   A little late, but a friend in Chase Manhattan's middle markets
department explained their side of the $45 canadian check story:



   "Some people have a hard time grasping the fact that different
countries have different central banks and the technology driving the
clearing of checks across borders is not all that it could be.  Generally
the common commercial practice for transacting business across borders is
with either letters-of-credit or electronic funds transfers, aka wires,
checks being used exclusively for intra-country transactions.  I always
tell my customers that if they receive a check from offshore, to tell the
remitter to stop payment on it and send a wire instead.

   It sounds like your friend, associate, colleague, whatever, is
frustrated because he does not understand.  I would tell him to call his
local congressional representative and advocate having the armed forces
storm across the US-Canadian border and conquer what could be ours for the
taking.  Then he won't have to worry about globalization." 



That is an interesting line of argument that, I am afraid, is quite common
in the corporate-speak.  It boils down to the following line "Your friend
had problem cashing a foreign check, because we do not use foreign checks
for international transfers, and we do not use foreign checks for
international transfers because (converting the passive voice) we do not
use foreign checks for international transfer."

Now comes the understanding part which is a bit ambiguous.  If it pertains
to the grasping of the fact that Chase Manhattan does not cash foreign
checks - the author misses the point entirely, because the fact that
foreign checks are not chashed was the subject of the initial complaint.
If, on the other hand, it pertains to the understanding of the logic "we do
not do it because we do not do it" that indeed requires years of corporate
brainwashing to take such a gem or newspeak wiht any degree of seriousness.


 
Wojtek Sokolowski 
Institute for Policy Studies
Johns Hopkins University
Baltimore, MD 21218
[EMAIL PROTECTED]
voice: (410) 516-4056
fax:   (410) 516-8233

Opinions expressed above are those of this writer only.  They do not
represent the views or policies of the Institute for Policy Studies, the
Johns Hopkins University, or anyone else affiliated with these institutions.








Chase Manhattan responds

1998-03-20 Thread boddhisatva





To whom,



A little late, but a friend in Chase Manhattan's middle markets
department explained their side of the $45 canadian check story:



"Some people have a hard time grasping the fact that different
countries have different central banks and the technology driving the
clearing of checks across borders is not all that it could be.  Generally
the common commercial practice for transacting business across borders is
with either letters-of-credit or electronic funds transfers, aka wires,
checks being used exclusively for intra-country transactions.  I always
tell my customers that if they receive a check from offshore, to tell the
remitter to stop payment on it and send a wire instead.

It sounds like your friend, associate, colleague, whatever, is
frustrated because he does not understand.  I would tell him to call his
local congressional representative and advocate having the armed forces
storm across the US-Canadian border and conquer what could be ours for the
taking.  Then he won't have to worry about globalization." 




'Nuff said, I guess.  






peace,


boddhisatva







Re: a proposed leading indicator

1998-03-20 Thread valis

Doug asks:
 Speaking of indicators, The Nation has asked me to put together a set of
 economic/social indicators, to be published quarterly, that would be
 revealing, interesting, and against the grain of conventional thinking.
 
 Any suggestions?

Harper's notorious Index has items based on all sorts of wickedly clever
criteria, most of which would fit that function.  Dig in.

   valis








Re: what's in a name?

1998-03-20 Thread Rakesh Bhandari

In yet another bolt of clarity Wojtek reminded us

It is one thing to say that Marxist theory explains some important aspects
of capitalist relations  of production (which I think it does), quite a
differnt thing to determine to what degree those capitalist relations of
production ar implemented in actual societies and to what extent they are
mitigated by historical contingencies,

Yes,it is one thing to study motion in a vacuum and then to determine the
modification of motion by air pressure or viscosity. So Marx may have
initially assumed a closed capitalist society, without foreign trade or
vestigal or intermediate classes.

Let us assume a closed national capitalist economy (which may not be Marx's
assumption). If the current stock of machinery or inventories of such
machinery  has suffered moral depreciation, this may represent a
destruction of value in an enclosed national capitalism. However if such
morally depreciated machinery can be sold *above value* either through
foreign direct investment (with most of the financing being domestic) or
through licensing agreements (according to Mansfield, et al 1982, the
average age of technologies transferred to their developing economy
subsidiaries by US firms during the 1960-1978 period was ten years and 13
years of technologies transferred through licensing; Mowery estimates
imports of capital equipment embody technologies that lies somewhere
between the age of those avaialbe through licensign and those transferred
to wholly-owned subsidiaries), then falling profitability on past
investments engendered by moral depreciation no longer obtains in an open
system. What may rather come to pass is the perenial debt of those who have
used loans to purchase equipment which is economically obsolescent in world
market terms.

But such modifications to capital's dynamics may not always be important.
To the extent that the dynamic of capital itself implies the destruction of
vestigal or intermediate classes, then capital's own development renders
less effective such interference to its own laws of motion.

Best,
Rakesh







RE: funny story about AER (was ASSA session cuts)

1998-03-20 Thread Rosser Jr, John Barkley

 I should have noted that the letter was a copy (also 
sent to the ICARE list) that was sent to John Siegfried, 
Secretary of the AEA.  I only learned from John Adams that 
he was the official author of the dump letter.  I went to 
grad school (U-Wisconsin-Madison) with him, so took the 
opportunity to make a more direct appeal.
Barkley Rosser
On Fri, 20 Mar 1998 12:27:00 -0500 "Fellows, Jeffrey" 
[EMAIL PROTECTED] wrote:

 A few years back, the University of Utah library tried to use journal
 usage as a method of deciding which journal subscriptions to maintain.
 They told patrons to leave the journals on the tables after examination,
 instead of reshelving them. After a period of time, the library began
 labelling the journals which were to have their subscriptions cancelled.
 The AER was on the list!
 
 As a qualifier, I think many of the few mainstream faculty (and the
 department) had the AER in their offices. I do doubt the AER was allowed
 to be cancelled, external program review problems and such, but it was a
 hoot to see the cancellation notice. I bet similar use studies (crude as
 it was) would produce the same results at many mainstream schools.
 
 Jeff
  --
 From: Colin Danby
 To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
 Subject: ASSA session cuts
 Date: Thursday, March 19, 1998 9:11PM
 
 Barkley:
 
 Great letter.  Is there any value in having more of us
 unwashed types write in support?  If so can you post a
 name and address to write to?
 
 Thanks, Colin
 
 PS If AEA is busily stifling us hets is there any good
 reason to remain a member?  I could easily manage
 without my own copies of its ubiquitous ( iniquitous)
 journals.

-- 
Rosser Jr, John Barkley
[EMAIL PROTECTED]







Re: a proposed leading indicator -Reply

1998-03-20 Thread Doug Henwood

Louis Proyect wrote:

Related to this is the question of the number of people living in
apartments, those who are not homeless but who are miserably crowded. The
NY Times ran articles last year about the horrible problems facing Mexican
and other immigrants who are crammed 10 to a one-bedroom apartment in
sections of Queens or the Bronx. Contagious illnesses like TB, fires, and
psychological stress make these places hell.

Speaking of which, I highly recommend Peter Kwong's book, Forbidden
Workers, recently out from the New Press. It's a study of illegal Chinese
immigrants (and Peter insists on using the word "illegal," not
undocumented), mostly in NYC. How they get here, why they left, what they
expect, and the mainly horrible fate that awaits them in the USA. 70 hour
workweeks @ $3 an hour - some of these in Chinatown sweatshops with UNITE!
contracts - living 15 to a room, sleeping in shifts on stacked bunks,
eating the meanest diet, suffering diseases of overwork and poverty, living
in intense social isolation. He's got a chapter, "Manufacturing Ethnicity,"
showing how the bosses use nationalist rhetoric to secure their status. A
compelling story, and an analytical model of how ethnicity and class work
together.

Doug







Re: what's in a name?

1998-03-20 Thread Wojtek Sokolowski

At 12:46 PM 3/20/98 -0500, you wrote:
   Mr. Sokolowski's post illustrates the misconception that socialism
and a command economy are anything like the same animal.  If socialism was a
command economy, then it would be true that the difference between socialism
and capitalism was a matter of degree.  Therefore, Marxists can happily
conclude that socialism is *not* characterized by the presence of a command
economy.  Instead, it is a question of ownership.  When ownership is
constituted in a capitalist way, we have capitalism.  If ownership was ever
to be constituted in a socialist way, we would have socialism.  Fortunately
for young socialists, ownership has never been constituted this way, and thus
the putative "socialist" regimes of the past need not be a millstone around
their necks.  



   There, that ought to finish *that* debate.  :)



I reply (WS:)  That is not what I arued for, but what I argued against --
the tendency of the bourgeois punditry to equate the Soviet economic regime
with "marxism" or socialism.  Since I alredy replied to a similar criticism
elsewhere, I will simply attach that posting here.

Regards,

WS

enclosure:

It seems to me that Wojtek's assessment of socialism vs capitalism is
quite wide 
of the mark.  First, Marx's theory (like any) is meant to explain
phenomena, not 
describe empirical reality (a notoriously slippery customer).  


My reply (WS): I was not talking about differences in the content of
abstract concepts or theoretical models using those concepts.  I am well
aware of the fact that human mind is capable of making really fine
conceptual distinctions.

From my standpoint, a theretical model can explain a chunk of reality only
when it fits that reality, that is, describes it accurately.  That does not
mean positivistic fetishism of 'emprical statements' which is closer to
cult thann empirical science (on that see, for example, my earlier postings
in opinion polls to this list).  It simply means that a theoretical model
must be relevant to empirical reality it purports to explain.

To illustrate that with a simple example, the rat-choice model underlying
the neo-classical economics explains the behaviour or rational economic
actors in nearly 100%.  The only problem is that the "rational human actor"
 exists only in that particular theory, and the rat-choice model's power to
explain real-life behaviour approaches zero.  So what we are having here is
a classical example of 'explanation' in a psychological sense only, an
'explanation' that gives us a feeling that we 'know what's going on'
without any empirical testing of that knowledge-- which is the same as
mythology or religion.

It is one thing to say that Marxist theory explains some important aspects
of capitalist relations  of production (which I think it does), quite a
differnt thing to determine to what degree those capitalist relations of
production ar implemented in actual societies and to what extent they are
mitigated by historical contingencies, and still a different thing (that
has little to do with Marxist theory itself) to see the empirical world as
the battle ground between 'marxist' or 'socialist' and 'free market' or
'capitalist' regimes.

My initial comments pertained mainly to the third 'thing' mentioned above.
It questioned the validity of the bulk of (mostly) American social science
that uses the dichotomy. 




Second, the test 
of between and within groups variance is a fine (theory) for statistical
analysis 
as a privileged criterion of validity.  



I reply (WS): The concept of partinioning variance, although the wroking
horse of statistical methods of data analysis, is hardly the exclusive
domain of statistics.  Statistics only adds a numerical 'spin' to it that
allows us to calculate the probability of random error (due to sampling),
but you can partition variance without the theory of probability.  For
example, if you assume that the cases in your data set represent the total
population rather than a sample drawn from the population, you can still
calculate the means and variances  for different groups of cases and
calculate the ratio of the 'explained' variance to either the 'unexplained'
or the 'total' variance.  What you will not do in such a case is
calculating the significance test, i.e. you would take your F ratio for its
face value rather than calculate the probability that its deviation from 1
is due to sampling error (since no such error exists for populations). 

The concept of partitioning of variance is directly related to the most
fundamental human cognitive faculty of making concpetuial distinctions and
categories -- grouping what is similar and separating what is dissimilar
(or the proverbial apples and oranges).  Statisticians did not invent it,
they merely proposed a different method of doing it.

In my original posting, I did not specifically call for calculating means
and variances from the means, although that is one of many possible methods
of approaching 

Re: a proposed leading indicator

1998-03-20 Thread James Devine

Sure, let's use an index of the prescription of Prozac, Ritalin, etc. But
for what? as a measure of how mentally ill our society is?

It's definitely true that it's not just individuals but society that's
mentally ill: egged on by school bureaucrats and drug companies -- and
allowed by scared and ignorant parents -- pediatricians who don't know
anything about mental illnesses are over-diagnosing attention deficit (and
hyperactivity) disorder and over-prescribing Ritalin. Further examples can
be listed, I am sure. 

We should be careful about rejecting these mental medications: not all are
bad, including Ritalin. There are kids for whom Ritalin works as
advertised. (The scuttlebut among parents is that you can tell that a kid
really has ADHD or ADD if the Ritalin works.) My son, who has a mild case
of autism (a.k.a. Asperger's Syndrome, which recently got its public debut
in NEWSWEEK), which have some side effects that seem to require Zoloft (a
Prozac substitute). (It's always a matter of experimentation and careful
observation to make sure the medication and the dosage are correct.)
Psychiatrists, a more expensive bunch than pediatricians, are the only ones
who should be prescribing this stuff.

In summary, the prescription of ment. meds should not be totally avoided as
much as treated with extreme caution. Unfortunately, the profit-driven
system with its top-down system of control won't allow that.   

The above should be titled "Jim Devine on Drugs." ;-)

in pen-l solidarity,

Jim Devine   [EMAIL PROTECTED] 
http://clawww.lmu.edu/1997F/ECON/jdevine.html
"A society is rich when material goods, including capital, are cheap, and
human beings dear."  -- R.H. Tawney.







a proposed leading indicator -Reply

1998-03-20 Thread Tim Stroshane

Doug, 

Glad to hear the Nation wants you to do such a regular feature. 
As a housing planner for Berkeley dealing with homeless policy,
services and programs, I have some indicators kinda close to my
heart for you to consider.

How about the number of estimated homeless population per 1,000
resident population?  Another indicator could perhaps include the
percent of households in America paying 50 percent of their
income in rent, then the percent of households at or below 50
percent of their regional median incomes who pay 50 percent of
their incomes in rent.  It would be interesting to gauge how the
poor fair relative to the middle class in that regard, and over
time.

I don't know if the nation's (small n) data sources on the
experience of welfare reform is up to the task, but some gauge of
how many people left the rolls after August 1996, by the reason
for their exit (e.g., having gotten a job versus being cut
because of non-compliance with their "work plans").

I would also suggest some health related indicators, including
perhaps AIDS cumulative  TB case rates, with resistant-strain
TB, as well as price indicators on the costs of various classes
of drugs, such as protease inhibitors and antibiotics.

Finally, a number of cities and communities around the country
have passed or are considering living wage ordinances of various
kinds and stripes.  Some sort of regional-oriented living wage
indicators would be interesting and useful, as an alternative to
the CPI.

To the extent you can get the Nation, with its New Look, to
incorporate good graphics, it seems you're the guy to do it.





RE: funny story about AER (was ASSA session cuts)

1998-03-20 Thread Fellows, Jeffrey

A few years back, the University of Utah library tried to use journal
usage as a method of deciding which journal subscriptions to maintain.
They told patrons to leave the journals on the tables after examination,
instead of reshelving them. After a period of time, the library began
labelling the journals which were to have their subscriptions cancelled.
The AER was on the list!

As a qualifier, I think many of the few mainstream faculty (and the
department) had the AER in their offices. I do doubt the AER was allowed
to be cancelled, external program review problems and such, but it was a
hoot to see the cancellation notice. I bet similar use studies (crude as
it was) would produce the same results at many mainstream schools.

Jeff
 --
From: Colin Danby
To: [EMAIL PROTECTED]
Subject: ASSA session cuts
Date: Thursday, March 19, 1998 9:11PM

Barkley:

Great letter.  Is there any value in having more of us
unwashed types write in support?  If so can you post a
name and address to write to?

Thanks, Colin

PS If AEA is busily stifling us hets is there any good
reason to remain a member?  I could easily manage
without my own copies of its ubiquitous ( iniquitous)
journals.





Re: a proposed leading indicator

1998-03-20 Thread Doug Henwood

Speaking of indicators, The Nation has asked me to put together a set of
economic/social indicators, to be published quarterly, that would be
revealing, interesting, and against the grain of conventional thinking.

Any suggestions?

Doug







Re: further progress in econonmics

1998-03-20 Thread Peter Dorman

Thanks, Doug.  In the past I have sometimes used slavery as an example
of the vacuousness of the pareto criterion.  It's nice to have a formal
proof.

Peter Dorman






Re: absurd (fwd)

1998-03-20 Thread boddhisatva






To whom...,





On Wednesday C. Rakesh Bhandari reminded us of the classic idea
about the financier - that he is a leech and a drain on society.  Although
every Marxist impulse drives me to agree, I must not.  As the question
about Japan becomes not whether it will crash but whether it will tunnel
into the earth and burn, it likewise becomes clear that the U.S. is doing
something right and the industrial super-producers are doing something
wrong.  It cannot be that the U.S. is competing on the industrial
production side, so let's simply concede that point and move on for the
moment.  The next reasonable conclusion is that the U.S. (and Britain) are
punishing workers so badly that they are making up the difference in
industrial production.  This does not seem, even to my jejune economic
eyes, to be reasonable.  The dollars and pounds just aren't there, it
seems.  That leaves another alternative. 



If we, as leftist economists (okay, if *you* as leftist
economists, and if I as a leftist duffer) agree that absent capitalist
hegemony there would be greater production, it makes sense that capitalism
can profit by getting out of its own way.  This does *not* boil down to
supply-side economics.  When market discipline actually *disciplines* the
vast bureaucratic police state that peoples the office towers of
capitalism, it may be that economic benefit, while not produced, comes
shining through.  It may be that production is down but not only is the
average price of a good more efficient, but the *liquidity* represented by
a good is greater.  By this I mean that the sale of a given good hits the
*capitalist* bottom line faster.  That capitalist bottom line is not cash,
but credit.  Credit is a market phenomenon.  Goods are a market
phenomenon.  Ideally they are as intimate as possible. 


When credit markets are king and investment bankers rule, it makes
sense to have these people running industry.  If nothing else, it gets
industrialist and banker on the same page.  Meanwhile, market discipline
has hit the world of credit with a vengeance.  Debt is securitized with
ease.  I recently found out that Chase Manhattan Bank has an internal
trading desk in loan swaps that has more than a thousand traders and has a
nominal open interest of more than a trillion dollars.  That is more than
the nominal open interest in the Chicago Mercantile Exchange.  Let the
keretsus have their societies of industrial mandarins, CMB has market
capitalism in its pocket. 


Therefore when Merck introduces a new drug, that drug's potential
success is translated quickly to Merck's stock price and bond rating. 
That allows the capitalists at Merck to use their improved,
market-rationalized credit to get into new technologies, or whatever.



Merck may not turn around and build a facility in the U.S., but it
may be able to build a foreign facility on good economic terms.  The cost
per good imported into the U.S. goes down, and living standards go up,
although the percentage of imports rises.  The wages of the working class
may be slowly settling to the bottom of the lake, but the "value" of what
they can buy is not. It's not long-term sound, but maybe it works that way
short-term. 



In any event, the bottom line is that if American capitalism is
expanding and increasingly market-efficient America has the potential to
do better.  This is not because of trickle-down, but because capitalists
are leveraging domestic markets more effectively.  Obviously this will not
last forever, but it may last as long as the investment liquidity is out
there - as long as the baby-boomers are buying stocks and bonds.  When the
boomers stop investing, the party is over.  When they start dis-investing,
the fun begins.  Meanwhile, short the Yen and fund the revolution.





peace


boddhisatva (on the green in four)










more Wall Street wisdom

1998-03-20 Thread Doug Henwood

I just heard a stock pundit in CNBC who was touting Pfizer, which has the
Street all, um, excited over its new impotence drug. "The stock just hit
90, and stocks that hit 90 almost always go to 100." See why these guys
make so much money?

Doug







Re: CONFERENCE (Binghamton): Work, Difference and Social Change

1998-03-20 Thread Anthony D'costa

Global Workplace"
Richard Sharpe, "Globalization: The Next Tactic in the 50-year Struggle
of Labour and Capital in Software Production"
--
Dear Phil:

I am in India researching the software industry.  Is there any way I can
get a copy of the above paper?

My address: Anthony D'Costa
203 Avensdale
5 Moyenville Road
Langford Town
Bangalore 560 025
India

E-mail:[EMAIL PROTECTED]





Re: a proposed leading indicator

1998-03-20 Thread Jay Hecht

Jim,

I like your idea!  Isn't there a "contrarinan" shool of invesment analysts who
use Time covers and the sort (I think somebody uses this at Barron's).  The
key thing, is that economists are so full of crap (most of the time) re:
"turning points" that your indicator is probably an indicator or a "hyper-
peak" in the business cycle.

Jason