To make Braunfeld analogy closer, wouldn't you'd need a law 
that said, "if you aren't open 24/7, you have to pay an $X tax" -- or, in the 
Sherbert context, "if you quit work without good cause, you have to pay a tax 
equal to X% of your unemployment compensation"?  I would think that either of 
these situations would indeed be seen as a substantial burden on religious 
practice (setting aside the separate discussion that Marty and I are having 
about whether the employer mandate isn't a burden because, even paying the tax, 
both secular and religious employers would come out ahead by dropping their 
insurance policies).  Or am I mistaken?

                Eugene

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Micah Schwartzman
Sent: Wednesday, December 18, 2013 7:19 AM
To: Law & Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

Even if some employers have to pay more under the 4980H(a) tax, would that be 
sufficient to show a substantial burden? In Braunfeld v. Brown, the Court held 
that laws may indirectly burden religious believers even when they impose "some 
financial sacrifice in order to observe their religious beliefs."

I'm not saying Braunfeld is fully analogous. The Sunday closing law did not 
require Orthodox Jews to violate their religious beliefs, but that law did make 
it more expensive for them to compete with businesses that opened on Saturday. 
(The Court also noted the state could have exempted Orthodox Jews from the 
closing law but did not, even though other states did offer such an exemption.)

Braunfeld might support Marty's argument. The government provides an option to 
all employers: (1) pay a tax, or (2) provide coverage. If (1) doesn't burden 
religion, and even if it's somewhat more expensive, Braunfeld seems to 
contemplate that laws will sometimes work in this way. Provided a law doesn't 
directly compel anyone to violate their religious beliefs, its imposition of 
additional costs on religious practice is not sufficient to show a substantial 
burden.

Marty didn't cite Braunfeld in his post, so maybe he wouldn't rely on it. And 
maybe there are other problems with the analogy, but I wonder if the "no 
employer mandate" argument turns on an empirical claim, at least if the cost 
differentials are not so significant as to be tantamount to coercion -- as in 
the 4980D tax for failing to comply with coverage requirements.

On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene wrote:


The heart of Marty's argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I think, an 
empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be better off just 
dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax, "us[ing] some of [the] 
enormous cost savings" to compensate employees for the lost coverage, thus 
keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the rest of the "enormous cost 
savings."  (Indeed, if employees grumble over the inconvenience or just the 
change, the employers can split some of the rest of the enormous cost savings 
with the employees -- a win-win proposition for employers and employees.)  And, 
if Marty is right, this would be true for employers generally, not just 
religious employers.  We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers 
to take advantage of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite 
regardless of God.

But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just the 
nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll taxes on 
the compensation payment to the employees.  It's not surprising that the 
Justice Department hasn't made this argument, since the Administration has long 
argued (unless I'm mistaken) that large employers won't drop employer-based 
health insurance.  And the Congressional Budget 
Office,http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop 
their health insurance, because "the legislation leaves in place substantial 
financial advantages for many people to receive insurance coverage through 
their employers, and it provides some new incentives for employers to offer 
insurance coverage to their employees."

Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be 
different.  But the CBO's estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is 
right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than gain 
from capturing some of the "enormous cost savings" -- by dropping health 
insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think Hobby Lobby 
and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even enforced as a tax, 
thus would be a substantial burden.

Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that support 
your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as the CBO's 
view?

Eugene


Marty writes:

1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of a 
$3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average cost 
for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it, closer to 
$10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.  (In any event, 
there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is significantly 
differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they have a workforce 
comprised of almost all single employees with no family coverage.)

In order to remain competitive for recruiting or retaining most of their 
employees, the plaintiffs wouldn't have to kick in any extra money in salary, 
because the employees would have their exchange-purchased plans subsidized by 
the federal government (both in terms of the cost-savings realized by virtue of 
the exchanges themselves as well as the government's premium tax credits and 
cost-sharing reductions.  To be sure, some of their more well-compensated 
employees might have paid less in premiums for the HL plan than they would to 
purchase a plan on the exchange (maybe -- again, there's no allegation or 
evidence of that here).  But to make up that hypothetical shortfall, and 
attract those employees, HL need only use some of its enormous cost savings to 
sweeten their salaries.  (This is presumably what the many large employers who 
do not provide plans will do.)

For all these reasons, it is difficult to imagine HL or CW --or, more to the 
point, the average large employer -- being financially worse off if it pays the 
assessment.  (And again, there's no allegation of facts that would alter that 
conclusion here, in any event.)
_______________________________________________
To post, send message to 
Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu<mailto:Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu>
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

_______________________________________________
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

Reply via email to