Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-28 Thread Marty Lederman
Sorry it took so long.  My response to Eugene and others raising the same
question is here:

http://balkin.blogspot.com/2013/12/hobby-lobby-part-iii-adoes-federal-law.html

As always, I welcome any critiques/suggestions from list-members, thanks.


On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 11:36 AM, Marty Lederman
lederman.ma...@gmail.comwrote:

 I apologize for not responding right away, but I'm slammed with other
 stuff.  There is a lot to say here, and I think it's important -- Eugene is
 raising some good questions.  I'll try to respond in the next day or so; in
 the meantime, I'm very grateful for all the reactions, both supportive and
 critical (and both!) . . . please keep them coming, thanks.


 On Tue, Dec 17, 2013 at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.eduwrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax,
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this
 would be true for employers generally, *not* just religious employers.
 We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage
 of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.



 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not
 just the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as
 payroll taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not
 surprising that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers
 *won’t* drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional
 Budget Office,
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their employees.”



 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping
 health insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think
 Hobby Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even
 enforced as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.



 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as
 the CBO’s view?



 Eugene






___
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-28 Thread Marci Hamilton
The holidays have made it difficult to keep up but I did want to respond to 
Michael.   The notion that the distinguishing of Sherbert and Yoder were pure 
legal fictions in Smith is unpersuasive.With respect to Sherbert, the 
Court's reasoning is actually accurate and reflects the Court's understanding 
of Smith as a case of first impression as the Justice's Conference notes show.

The distinguishing of Yoder is unpersuasive but it appears the Court was 
reinforcing what Yoder was until RFRA -- an outlier.  Literally the only case 
to apply strict scrutiny to a neutral, generally applicable law, with little or 
no precedential value.   Its value is even more questionable today when 
children's interests would have to be taken into account and, therefore, 
Douglass's view would likely change the result, especially now that we have 
strong evidence of the harm done to Amish children by the failure to educate 
them.

All of this matters, because it is my view that RFRA in these cases is as 
unconstitutional as it was in Boerne.  The Court did not limit its reasoning to 
state law and relied explicitly on separation of powers.  Politics, not the 
Court, transformed Boerne into a decision only relevant to state law.As I 
have said before, and may have missed either Eugene's or Marty's responses over 
the holiday, their debate is one the courts are ill-suited to decide. 

If the Court takes this approach, the mandate cases will be an excellent 
example of how RFRA turns courts into legislatures and makes them lawmakers (in 
the tradition actually of the Lochner cases where strict scrutiny was employed 
to permit the courts to second guess employment laws), without the competence 
to do so.  

The problem of course is that the DOJ has failed to attack RFRA's 
constitutionality but that is, once again, politics, not constitutional 
analysis.


Marci


Marci A. Hamilton
Verkuil Chair in Public Law
Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
Yeshiva University
@Marci_Hamilton 



On Dec 18, 2013, at 4:54 PM, Michael Worley mwor...@byulaw.net wrote:

 You have a fair point;  I'm uncomfortable with Reynolds, but that doesn't 
 mean there weren't less protections for religion pre-incorporation.  However, 
 the distinguishing of Yoder and Sherbert (not to mention Cantwell) in Smith 
 is just a legal fiction Scalia made up.  The Law Review article by James D. 
 Gordon III Free exercise on the Mountaintop illustrates well the problems 
 with the theory that Smith was right
 
 
 On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 2:37 PM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.com wrote:
 This reasoning is based on the mythology created around the free exercise 
 clause by the reactions to Smith and the misrepresentations about the 
 doctrine to Congress.  It is quite remarkable this many years later so many 
 continue to parrot what is in fact untrue.  Yoder was an outlier and 
 Sherbert was not applied outside unemployment.  And the Justices thought in 
 those terms during the Term Smith was decided.
 
   Now folks may well want a different regime than pre-Smith but it would be 
 refreshing to see at least scholars (if not litigators) accurately discuss 
 the actual doctrine and not the doctrine they prefer.   
 
 The New York ACA case yesterday including indefensible reasoning on what 
 RFRA is and what the doctrine was before.  For example, the court cites to 
 Michael mcConnell's article, for the proposition that mandatory exemptions 
 were common at the time of the framing, a theory the Justices have rejected 
 and Ellis West and Philip Hamburger have shown to be deeply flawed 
 historically.  In my own work on liberty vs licentiousness, it is abundantly 
 clear the framers were far closer to the Smith way of reasoning than 
 mandatory accommodation.
 
 Marci
 
 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton 
 
 
 
 On Dec 18, 2013, at 9:45 AM, Michael Worley mwor...@byulaw.net wrote:
 
 And yet, without some form of heightened scrutiny, the free exercise clause 
 becomes a shell-- a hollow clause.  I'm not saying RFRA gets the balancing 
 right (I could make that argument, but I'm not), I'm saying that we have to 
 let judges do this balancing in some way.  Otherwise the Free Exercise 
 Clause will become as important as the Ninth Amendment is to contemporary 
 jurisprudence.  And Employment Division's principles apply to churches, not 
 just the litigants in this set of cases.
 
 There are plenty of 14th Amendment cases (think Brown and subsequent busing 
 cases in lower courts) where judges have acted as super-legislatures. 
 Why?  To protect rights!
 
 Michael
 
 
 On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 3:46 AM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.com wrote:
 This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications for 
 public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts into 
 super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne 
 ruled.  No court in my 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Marci Hamilton
This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications for 
public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts into 
super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne ruled.  No 
court in my view is institutionally competent to make these assessments and no 
judge, who is unaccountable to the electorate, should.  

Marci

Marci A. Hamilton
Verkuil Chair in Public Law
Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
Yeshiva University
@Marci_Hamilton 



On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu wrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I think, 
 an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be better off 
 just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax, “us[ing] some of 
 [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for the lost coverage, 
 thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the rest of the 
 “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over the 
 inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the rest of 
 the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win proposition for 
 employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this would be true for 
 employers generally, not just religious employers.  We should thus expect a 
 large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage of this option, purely 
 out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.
  
 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just 
 the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll 
 taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not surprising that 
 the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the Administration 
 has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers won’t drop 
 employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional Budget Office, 
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
  likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop 
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place substantial 
 financial advantages for many people to receive insurance coverage through 
 their employers, and it provides some new incentives for employers to offer 
 insurance coverage to their employees.” 
  
 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be 
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is 
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than 
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping health 
 insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think Hobby 
 Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even enforced 
 as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.
  
 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that 
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as 
 the CBO’s view?
  
 Eugene
  
  
 Marty writes:
  
 1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of a 
 $3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average cost 
 for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it, closer to 
 $10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.  (In any event, 
 there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is significantly 
 differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they have a 
 workforce comprised of almost all single employees with no family coverage.)
 
 In order to remain competitive for recruiting or retaining most of their 
 employees, the plaintiffs wouldn't have to kick in any extra money in salary, 
 because the employees would have their exchange-purchased plans subsidized by 
 the federal government (both in terms of the cost-savings realized by virtue 
 of the exchanges themselves as well as the government's premium tax credits 
 and cost-sharing reductions.  To be sure, some of their more well-compensated 
 employees might have paid less in premiums for the HL plan than they would to 
 purchase a plan on the exchange (maybe -- again, there's no allegation or 
 evidence of that here).  But to make up that hypothetical shortfall, and 
 attract those employees, HL need only use some of its enormous cost savings 
 to sweeten their salaries.  (This is presumably what the many large employers 
 who do not provide plans will do.)  
 
 For all these reasons, it is difficult to imagine HL or CW --or, more to the 
 point, the average large employer -- being financially worse off if it pays 
 the assessment.  (And again, there's no allegation of facts that would alter 
 that conclusion here, in any event.)
 
 ___
 To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
 To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Michael Worley
And yet, without some form of heightened scrutiny, the free exercise clause
becomes a shell-- a hollow clause.  I'm not saying RFRA gets the balancing
right (I could make that argument, but I'm not), I'm saying that we have to
let judges do this balancing in some way.  Otherwise the Free Exercise
Clause will become as important as the Ninth Amendment is to contemporary
jurisprudence.  And *Employment Division*'s principles apply to churches,
not just the litigants in this set of cases.

There are plenty of 14th Amendment cases (think *Brown *and subsequent
busing cases in lower courts) where judges have acted as
super-legislatures. Why?  To protect rights!

Michael


On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 3:46 AM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.com wrote:

 This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications for
 public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts into
 super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne ruled.
  No court in my view is institutionally competent to make these assessments
 and no judge, who is unaccountable to the electorate, should.

 Marci

 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton



 On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu wrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax,
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this
 would be true for employers generally, *not* just religious employers.
 We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage
 of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.



 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just
 the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll
 taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not surprising
 that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers
 *won’t* drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional
 Budget Office,
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their employees.”



 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping
 health insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think
 Hobby Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even
 enforced as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.



 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as
 the CBO’s view?



 Eugene





 Marty writes:



 1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of a
 $3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average
 cost for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it,
 closer to $10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.
 (In any event, there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is
 significantly differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they
 have a workforce comprised of almost all single employees with no family
 coverage.)


 In order to remain competitive for recruiting or retaining most of their
 employees, the plaintiffs wouldn't have to kick in any extra money in
 salary, because the employees would have their exchange-purchased plans
 subsidized by the federal government (both in terms of the cost-savings
 realized by virtue of the exchanges themselves as well as the government's
 premium tax credits and cost-sharing reductions.  To be sure, some of their
 more well-compensated employees *might* have paid less in premiums for
 the HL plan than they would to purchase a plan on the exchange (*maybe*-- 
 again, there's no allegation or evidence of that 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Paul Horwitz
I don't think it becomes the equivalent of the Ninth Amendment, or a shell, 
without heightened scrutiny as a freestanding principle. And I say that as a 
fan of the pre-Smith regime. Rather, it becomes an equality/speech provision, 
like the rest of the modern First Amendment. I am by no means a fan of that 
tendency. But it still leaves the clause as something, not nothing.

 On Dec 18, 2013, at 9:01 AM, Michael Worley mwor...@byulaw.net wrote:
 
 And yet, without some form of heightened scrutiny, the free exercise clause 
 becomes a shell-- a hollow clause.  I'm not saying RFRA gets the balancing 
 right (I could make that argument, but I'm not), I'm saying that we have to 
 let judges do this balancing in some way.  Otherwise the Free Exercise Clause 
 will become as important as the Ninth Amendment is to contemporary 
 jurisprudence.  And Employment Division's principles apply to churches, not 
 just the litigants in this set of cases.
 
 There are plenty of 14th Amendment cases (think Brown and subsequent busing 
 cases in lower courts) where judges have acted as super-legislatures. Why?  
 To protect rights!
 
 Michael
 
 
 On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 3:46 AM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.com wrote:
 This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications for 
 public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts into 
 super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne ruled.  
 No court in my view is institutionally competent to make these assessments 
 and no judge, who is unaccountable to the electorate, should.  
 
 Marci
 
 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton 
 
 
 
 On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu wrote:
 
 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I 
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be 
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax, 
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for 
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the 
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over 
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the 
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win 
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this 
 would be true for employers generally, not just religious employers.  We 
 should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage of 
 this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.
 
  
 
 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just 
 the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll 
 taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not surprising 
 that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the 
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers 
 won’t drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional Budget 
 Office, 
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
  likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop 
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place 
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance 
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for 
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their employees.” 
 
  
 
 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be 
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is 
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than 
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping 
 health insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think 
 Hobby Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even 
 enforced as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.
 
  
 
 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that 
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as 
 the CBO’s view?
 
  
 
 Eugene
 
  
 
  
 
 Marty writes:
 
  
 
 1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of a 
 $3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average 
 cost for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it, 
 closer to $10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.  
 (In any event, there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is 
 significantly differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they 
 have a workforce comprised of almost all single employees with no family 
 coverage.)
 
 
 In order to remain competitive for recruiting or retaining most of their 
 employees, the 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Michael Worley
Even Free Speech violations about time, place and manner get intermediate
(heightened) scrutiny.  My reading of Smith suggest Free Exercise claims do
not.


On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 8:08 AM, Paul Horwitz phorw...@hotmail.com wrote:

 I don't think it becomes the equivalent of the Ninth Amendment, or a
 shell, without heightened scrutiny as a freestanding principle. And I say
 that as a fan of the pre-Smith regime. Rather, it becomes an
 equality/speech provision, like the rest of the modern First Amendment. I
 am by no means a fan of that tendency. But it still leaves the clause as
 something, not nothing.

 On Dec 18, 2013, at 9:01 AM, Michael Worley mwor...@byulaw.net wrote:

 And yet, without some form of heightened scrutiny, the free exercise
 clause becomes a shell-- a hollow clause.  I'm not saying RFRA gets the
 balancing right (I could make that argument, but I'm not), I'm saying that
 we have to let judges do this balancing in some way.  Otherwise the Free
 Exercise Clause will become as important as the Ninth Amendment is to
 contemporary jurisprudence.  And *Employment Division*'s principles apply
 to churches, not just the litigants in this set of cases.

 There are plenty of 14th Amendment cases (think *Brown *and subsequent
 busing cases in lower courts) where judges have acted as
 super-legislatures. Why?  To protect rights!

 Michael


 On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 3:46 AM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.comwrote:

 This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications
 for public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts
 into super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne
 ruled.  No court in my view is institutionally competent to make these
 assessments and no judge, who is unaccountable to the electorate, should.

 Marci

 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton



 On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu
 wrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax,
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this
 would be true for employers generally, *not* just religious employers.
 We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage
 of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.



 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not
 just the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as
 payroll taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not
 surprising that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers
 *won’t* drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional
 Budget Office,
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their employees.”



 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping
 health insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think
 Hobby Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even
 enforced as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.



 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as
 the CBO’s view?



 Eugene





 Marty writes:



 1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of
 a $3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average
 cost for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it,
 closer to $10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.
 (In any event, there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is
 significantly differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they
 have a workforce comprised of 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Micah Schwartzman
Even if some employers have to pay more under the 4980H(a) tax, would that be 
sufficient to show a substantial burden? In Braunfeld v. Brown, the Court held 
that laws may indirectly burden religious believers even when they impose some 
financial sacrifice in order to observe their religious beliefs. 

I'm not saying Braunfeld is fully analogous. The Sunday closing law did not 
require Orthodox Jews to violate their religious beliefs, but that law did make 
it more expensive for them to compete with businesses that opened on Saturday. 
(The Court also noted the state could have exempted Orthodox Jews from the 
closing law but did not, even though other states did offer such an exemption.)

Braunfeld might support Marty's argument. The government provides an option to 
all employers: (1) pay a tax, or (2) provide coverage. If (1) doesn't burden 
religion, and even if it's somewhat more expensive, Braunfeld seems to 
contemplate that laws will sometimes work in this way. Provided a law doesn't 
directly compel anyone to violate their religious beliefs, its imposition of 
additional costs on religious practice is not sufficient to show a substantial 
burden. 

Marty didn't cite Braunfeld in his post, so maybe he wouldn't rely on it. And 
maybe there are other problems with the analogy, but I wonder if the no 
employer mandate argument turns on an empirical claim, at least if the cost 
differentials are not so significant as to be tantamount to coercion -- as in 
the 4980D tax for failing to comply with coverage requirements. 

On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene wrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I think, 
 an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be better off 
 just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax, “us[ing] some of 
 [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for the lost coverage, 
 thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the rest of the 
 “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over the 
 inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the rest of 
 the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win proposition for 
 employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this would be true for 
 employers generally, not just religious employers.  We should thus expect a 
 large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage of this option, purely 
 out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.
  
 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just 
 the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll 
 taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not surprising that 
 the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the Administration 
 has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers won’t drop 
 employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional Budget 
 Office,http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
  likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop 
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place substantial 
 financial advantages for many people to receive insurance coverage through 
 their employers, and it provides some new incentives for employers to offer 
 insurance coverage to their employees.” 
  
 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be 
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is 
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than 
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping health 
 insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think Hobby 
 Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even enforced 
 as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.
  
 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that 
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as 
 the CBO’s view?
  
 Eugene
  
  
 Marty writes:
  
 1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of a 
 $3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average cost 
 for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it, closer to 
 $10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.  (In any event, 
 there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is significantly 
 differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they have a 
 workforce comprised of almost all single employees with no family coverage.)
 
 In order to remain competitive for recruiting or retaining most of their 
 employees, the plaintiffs wouldn't have to kick in any extra money in salary, 
 because the employees would have their exchange-purchased plans subsidized by 
 the federal government (both in terms of the cost-savings realized by virtue 
 of the 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Marty Lederman
I apologize for not responding right away, but I'm slammed with other
stuff.  There is a lot to say here, and I think it's important -- Eugene is
raising some good questions.  I'll try to respond in the next day or so; in
the meantime, I'm very grateful for all the reactions, both supportive and
critical (and both!) . . . please keep them coming, thanks.


On Tue, Dec 17, 2013 at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu wrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax,
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this
 would be true for employers generally, *not* just religious employers.
 We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage
 of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.



 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just
 the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll
 taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not surprising
 that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers
 *won’t* drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional
 Budget Office,
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their employees.”



 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping
 health insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think
 Hobby Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even
 enforced as a tax, thus would be a substantial burden.



 Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that
 support your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see as
 the CBO’s view?



 Eugene





 Marty writes:



 1.  On your first point, even if the 4980H(a) tax were the equivalent of a
 $3000 assessment (because it's paid with after-tax dollars), the average
 cost for providing health insurance to employees is, as I understand it,
 closer to $10,000, so the employer would save about $7000 per employee.
 (In any event, there are no allegations in these cases that HL or CW is
 significantly differently situated than a typical employer, e.g., that they
 have a workforce comprised of almost all single employees with no family
 coverage.)


 In order to remain competitive for recruiting or retaining most of their
 employees, the plaintiffs wouldn't have to kick in any extra money in
 salary, because the employees would have their exchange-purchased plans
 subsidized by the federal government (both in terms of the cost-savings
 realized by virtue of the exchanges themselves as well as the government's
 premium tax credits and cost-sharing reductions.  To be sure, some of their
 more well-compensated employees *might* have paid less in premiums for
 the HL plan than they would to purchase a plan on the exchange (*maybe*-- 
 again, there's no allegation or evidence of that here).  But to make up
 *that* hypothetical shortfall, and attract those employees, HL need only
 use some of its enormous cost savings to sweeten their salaries.  (This is
 presumably what the many large employers who do not provide plans will
 do.)

 For all these reasons, it is difficult to imagine HL or CW --or, more to
 the point, the average large employer -- being financially *worse off* if
 it pays the assessment.  (And again, there's no allegation of facts that
 would alter that conclusion here, in any event.)

 ___
 To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
 To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see
 http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

 Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as
 private.  Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages 

RE: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Alan Brownstein
Rick asks an important question. We can step back from the constraints of the 
current litigation and think about how this issue should be resolved on a clean 
slate, (This analysis also requires ignoring the polarized and dysfunctional 
governments that exist at the national level and in many states.) One basic 
model for resolving this issue and some others involving the provision of 
intangible and fungible goods, would suggest: 1. that government exempt 
conscientious objectors from the operation of the statute; 2. that government 
provide the insurance coverage to which they would otherwise be entitled to the 
employees of exempt employers; 3. that if exempt employers save money as a 
result of the exemption, they should contribute an equivalent amount to some 
government identified public goods that are consistent with their faith -- 
thereby mitigating if not eliminating the cost to government of providing the 
insurance coverage to the employees of exempt employers, and also mitigating if 
not eliminating any incentive to assert a sham claim to an exemption just to 
receive the secular benefits that result from the exemption.

Marty's argument that there really is no mandate essentially suggests that the 
Affordable Care Act does this preemptively by giving all employers an 
alternative to providing the insurance coverage that some oppose on religious 
grounds. While Marty and Eugene very ably discuss whether the Affordable Care 
Act really gives employers an adequate alternative to providing the insurance, 
we should not lose sight of the foundation of their very thoughtful posts.  A 
system that provides for alternative duties or obligations consistent with the 
objector's faith by requiring appropriate alternative contributions that 
indirectly offset the costs to government of making sure that the beneficiaries 
of the statute do not lose out does not substantially burden religious persons 
nor does it impose unreasonable costs on government or third parties.

Not all accommodation issues can be resolved under this approach. Perhaps most 
cannot. But some can. If we are going to live together in a religiously 
pluralistic society in which government tries to respect the autonomy and 
dignity of all persons, isn't this kind of compromise the best approach to 
solving a problem like this one. 

Alan



From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu [religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] 
on behalf of Rick Garnett [rgarn...@nd.edu]
Sent: Wednesday, December 18, 2013 9:12 AM
To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: RE: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

Dear friends,

I’m also grateful to Eugene, Marty, Nelson, Micah, Fred, and many, many others 
who have been blogging and writing – carefully and insightfully – about the HHS 
cases.  I wanted to raise a not particularly technical or doctrinal question 
that has been on my own mind as I think about the cases:

Let’s put aside (just for now) our conversations and disagreements about the 
meaning and applicability of RFRA (that is, about whether or not that statute 
requires an accommodation for some objecting and non-exempt employers) and also 
about whether the Establishment Clause precludes such an accommodation.  Let’s 
put ourselves, instead, in the position of legislators (or staffers!) drafting 
the ACA, or administrators (or staffers!) drafting the relevant rules, in the 
first instance.

Let’s say we’ve decided that preventive services should be available to all 
women without cost sharing and that these services should those that are at 
issue in the HHS lawsuits.  We know that some employers – not many, but some; 
primarily religiously affiliated, but not all – will have religion-based 
objections to providing coverage that includes these services to their 
employees.   Would we have any good reasons affirmatively to decide *not* to 
craft the statute or regulations in such a way that the employees of objecting 
employers would receive the services in question via a mechanism or route that 
avoided the objection and accommodated the objectors?

Perhaps no such alternative mechanism or route – one that delivered the 
services without additional inconvenience or cost to the beneficiaries -- was 
or is feasible.   Others on this list have more direct experience than I do 
with these matters, but my impression is that alternatives were and remain 
possible.  We would want any such alternative to not involve inconvenience or 
disadvantage to the beneficiaries or to give the objecting employers any kind 
of financial windfall or competitive advantage.  But, again, I assume such an 
alternative could have been designed.  (If I’m wrong about this, then the 
objecting employers are, it seems to me, in a weaker position.)

Perhaps, instead, our reasons for not accommodating would have to do with costs 
of another kind:  We might think that accommodating these employers would

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread David Cruz
Alan,

Did you mean the two quoted passages below to be equivalent?  They seem 
somewhat different (at least potentially) to me.  That is, the cost of having 
the government rather than employers provide a benefit might outstrip the 
amount an employer gains by not providing the benefit, might it not?  Does that 
potential “efficiency” discrepancy matter for your analysis?

David B. Cruz
Professor of Law
University of Southern California Gould School of Law
Los Angeles, CA 90089-0071
U.S.A.


From: A.E. Brownstein 
aebrownst...@ucdavis.edumailto:aebrownst...@ucdavis.edu
Reply-To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics 
religionlaw@lists.ucla.edumailto:religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics 
religionlaw@lists.ucla.edumailto:religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
Subject: RE: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

[snip] 3. that if exempt employers save money as a result of the exemption, 
they should contribute an equivalent amount [snip]

[snip] the costs to government of making sure that the beneficiaries of the 
statute do not lose out [snip]
___
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Marci Hamilton
This reasoning is based on the mythology created around the free exercise 
clause by the reactions to Smith and the misrepresentations about the doctrine 
to Congress.  It is quite remarkable this many years later so many continue to 
parrot what is in fact untrue.  Yoder was an outlier and Sherbert was not 
applied outside unemployment.  And the Justices thought in those terms during 
the Term Smith was decided.

  Now folks may well want a different regime than pre-Smith but it would be 
refreshing to see at least scholars (if not litigators) accurately discuss the 
actual doctrine and not the doctrine they prefer.   

The New York ACA case yesterday including indefensible reasoning on what RFRA 
is and what the doctrine was before.  For example, the court cites to Michael 
mcConnell's article, for the proposition that mandatory exemptions were common 
at the time of the framing, a theory the Justices have rejected and Ellis West 
and Philip Hamburger have shown to be deeply flawed historically.  In my own 
work on liberty vs licentiousness, it is abundantly clear the framers were far 
closer to the Smith way of reasoning than mandatory accommodation.

Marci

Marci A. Hamilton
Verkuil Chair in Public Law
Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
Yeshiva University
@Marci_Hamilton 



On Dec 18, 2013, at 9:45 AM, Michael Worley mwor...@byulaw.net wrote:

 And yet, without some form of heightened scrutiny, the free exercise clause 
 becomes a shell-- a hollow clause.  I'm not saying RFRA gets the balancing 
 right (I could make that argument, but I'm not), I'm saying that we have to 
 let judges do this balancing in some way.  Otherwise the Free Exercise Clause 
 will become as important as the Ninth Amendment is to contemporary 
 jurisprudence.  And Employment Division's principles apply to churches, not 
 just the litigants in this set of cases.
 
 There are plenty of 14th Amendment cases (think Brown and subsequent busing 
 cases in lower courts) where judges have acted as super-legislatures. Why?  
 To protect rights!
 
 Michael
 
 
 On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 3:46 AM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.com wrote:
 This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications for 
 public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts into 
 super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne ruled.  
 No court in my view is institutionally competent to make these assessments 
 and no judge, who is unaccountable to the electorate, should.  
 
 Marci
 
 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton 
 
 
 
 On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu wrote:
 
 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I 
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be 
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax, 
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for 
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the 
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over 
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the 
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win 
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this 
 would be true for employers generally, not just religious employers.  We 
 should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage of 
 this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.
 
  
 
 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just 
 the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll 
 taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not surprising 
 that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the 
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers 
 won’t drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional Budget 
 Office, 
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
  likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop 
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place 
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance 
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for 
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their employees.” 
 
  
 
 Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be 
 different.  But the CBO’s estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is 
 right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than 
 gain from capturing some of the “enormous cost savings” -- by dropping 
 health insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think 
 Hobby Lobby and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even 
 

Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Michael Worley
You have a fair point;  I'm uncomfortable with *Reynolds*, but that doesn't
mean there weren't less protections for religion pre-incorporation.
 However, the distinguishing of *Yoder *and *Sherbert* (not to mention
*Cantwell*) in *Smith* is just a legal fiction Scalia made up.  The Law
Review article by James D. Gordon III Free exercise on the Mountaintop
illustrates well the problems with the theory that *Smith* was right


On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 2:37 PM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.com wrote:

 This reasoning is based on the mythology created around the free exercise
 clause by the reactions to Smith and the misrepresentations about the
 doctrine to Congress.  It is quite remarkable this many years later so many
 continue to parrot what is in fact untrue.  Yoder was an outlier and
 Sherbert was not applied outside unemployment.  And the Justices thought in
 those terms during the Term Smith was decided.

   Now folks may well want a different regime than pre-Smith but it would
 be refreshing to see at least scholars (if not litigators) accurately
 discuss the actual doctrine and not the doctrine they prefer.

 The New York ACA case yesterday including indefensible reasoning on what
 RFRA is and what the doctrine was before.  For example, the court cites to
 Michael mcConnell's article, for the proposition that mandatory exemptions
 were common at the time of the framing, a theory the Justices have rejected
 and Ellis West and Philip Hamburger have shown to be deeply flawed
 historically.  In my own work on liberty vs licentiousness, it is
 abundantly clear the framers were far closer to the Smith way of reasoning
 than mandatory accommodation.

 Marci

 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton



 On Dec 18, 2013, at 9:45 AM, Michael Worley mwor...@byulaw.net wrote:

 And yet, without some form of heightened scrutiny, the free exercise
 clause becomes a shell-- a hollow clause.  I'm not saying RFRA gets the
 balancing right (I could make that argument, but I'm not), I'm saying that
 we have to let judges do this balancing in some way.  Otherwise the Free
 Exercise Clause will become as important as the Ninth Amendment is to
 contemporary jurisprudence.  And *Employment Division*'s principles apply
 to churches, not just the litigants in this set of cases.

 There are plenty of 14th Amendment cases (think *Brown *and subsequent
 busing cases in lower courts) where judges have acted as
 super-legislatures. Why?  To protect rights!

 Michael


 On Wed, Dec 18, 2013 at 3:46 AM, Marci Hamilton hamilto...@aol.comwrote:

 This exchange, which shows both Marty and Eugene's high qualifications
 for public service, underscores how RFRA (and RLUIPA) turn federal courts
 into super legislatures and violate the separation of powers -- as Boerne
 ruled.  No court in my view is institutionally competent to make these
 assessments and no judge, who is unaccountable to the electorate, should.

 Marci

 Marci A. Hamilton
 Verkuil Chair in Public Law
 Benjamin N. Cardozo Law School
 Yeshiva University
 @Marci_Hamilton



 On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene vol...@law.ucla.edu
 wrote:

 The heart of Marty’s argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I
 think, an empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be
 better off just dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax,
 “us[ing] some of [the] enormous cost savings” to compensate employees for
 the lost coverage, thus keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the
 rest of the “enormous cost savings.”  (Indeed, if employees grumble over
 the inconvenience or just the change, the employers can split some of the
 rest of the enormous cost savings with the employees -- a win-win
 proposition for employers and employees.)  And, if Marty is right, this
 would be true for employers generally, *not* just religious employers.
 We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers to take advantage
 of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite regardless of God.



 But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not
 just the nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as
 payroll taxes on the compensation payment to the employees.  It’s not
 surprising that the Justice Department hasn’t made this argument, since the
 Administration has long argued (unless I’m mistaken) that large employers
 *won’t* drop employer-based health insurance.  And the Congressional
 Budget Office,
 http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop
 their health insurance, because “the legislation leaves in place
 substantial financial advantages for many people to receive insurance
 coverage through their employers, and it provides some new incentives for
 employers to offer insurance coverage to their 

RE: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Alan Brownstein
David's correct that there may be a discrepancy here --- and the greater the 
discrepancy the greater the cost to government and the public of providing the 
accommodation.

I think the discrepancy is likely to be smaller rather than larger in cases 
involving government mandates requiring third parties (like employers) to 
provide intangible, fungible benefits (like money or insurance coverage) to 
their employees.

I also think that it is constitutionally permissible and normatively 
appropriate for the government to incur some costs to accommodate religious 
exercise - although it may not be clear in many cases how the cost should be 
measured and when it becomes unacceptably high.

Alan

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of David Cruz
Sent: Wednesday, December 18, 2013 11:24 AM
To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

Alan,

Did you mean the two quoted passages below to be equivalent?  They seem 
somewhat different (at least potentially) to me.  That is, the cost of having 
the government rather than employers provide a benefit might outstrip the 
amount an employer gains by not providing the benefit, might it not?  Does that 
potential efficiency discrepancy matter for your analysis?

David B. Cruz
Professor of Law
University of Southern California Gould School of Law
Los Angeles, CA 90089-0071
U.S.A.


From: A.E. Brownstein 
aebrownst...@ucdavis.edumailto:aebrownst...@ucdavis.edu
Reply-To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics 
religionlaw@lists.ucla.edumailto:religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics 
religionlaw@lists.ucla.edumailto:religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
Subject: RE: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

[snip] 3. that if exempt employers save money as a result of the exemption, 
they should contribute an equivalent amount [snip]

[snip] the costs to government of making sure that the beneficiaries of the 
statute do not lose out [snip]
___
To post, send message to Religionlaw@lists.ucla.edu
To subscribe, unsubscribe, change options, or get password, see 
http://lists.ucla.edu/cgi-bin/mailman/listinfo/religionlaw

Please note that messages sent to this large list cannot be viewed as private.  
Anyone can subscribe to the list and read messages that are posted; people can 
read the Web archives; and list members can (rightly or wrongly) forward the 
messages to others.

RE: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

2013-12-18 Thread Volokh, Eugene
To make Braunfeld analogy closer, wouldn't you'd need a law 
that said, if you aren't open 24/7, you have to pay an $X tax -- or, in the 
Sherbert context, if you quit work without good cause, you have to pay a tax 
equal to X% of your unemployment compensation?  I would think that either of 
these situations would indeed be seen as a substantial burden on religious 
practice (setting aside the separate discussion that Marty and I are having 
about whether the employer mandate isn't a burden because, even paying the tax, 
both secular and religious employers would come out ahead by dropping their 
insurance policies).  Or am I mistaken?

Eugene

From: religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu 
[mailto:religionlaw-boun...@lists.ucla.edu] On Behalf Of Micah Schwartzman
Sent: Wednesday, December 18, 2013 7:19 AM
To: Law  Religion issues for Law Academics
Subject: Re: Are large employers really better off dropping health insurance?

Even if some employers have to pay more under the 4980H(a) tax, would that be 
sufficient to show a substantial burden? In Braunfeld v. Brown, the Court held 
that laws may indirectly burden religious believers even when they impose some 
financial sacrifice in order to observe their religious beliefs.

I'm not saying Braunfeld is fully analogous. The Sunday closing law did not 
require Orthodox Jews to violate their religious beliefs, but that law did make 
it more expensive for them to compete with businesses that opened on Saturday. 
(The Court also noted the state could have exempted Orthodox Jews from the 
closing law but did not, even though other states did offer such an exemption.)

Braunfeld might support Marty's argument. The government provides an option to 
all employers: (1) pay a tax, or (2) provide coverage. If (1) doesn't burden 
religion, and even if it's somewhat more expensive, Braunfeld seems to 
contemplate that laws will sometimes work in this way. Provided a law doesn't 
directly compel anyone to violate their religious beliefs, its imposition of 
additional costs on religious practice is not sufficient to show a substantial 
burden.

Marty didn't cite Braunfeld in his post, so maybe he wouldn't rely on it. And 
maybe there are other problems with the analogy, but I wonder if the no 
employer mandate argument turns on an empirical claim, at least if the cost 
differentials are not so significant as to be tantamount to coercion -- as in 
the 4980D tax for failing to comply with coverage requirements.

On Dec 17, 2013, at 9:10 PM, Volokh, Eugene wrote:


The heart of Marty's argument (I focus for now on item 1 below) is, I think, an 
empirical claim:  Large employers such as Hobby Lobby would be better off just 
dropping coverage, paying the $2000/employee/year tax, us[ing] some of [the] 
enormous cost savings to compensate employees for the lost coverage, thus 
keeping the employees happy, and then pocketing the rest of the enormous cost 
savings.  (Indeed, if employees grumble over the inconvenience or just the 
change, the employers can split some of the rest of the enormous cost savings 
with the employees -- a win-win proposition for employers and employees.)  And, 
if Marty is right, this would be true for employers generally, not just 
religious employers.  We should thus expect a large fraction of savvy employers 
to take advantage of this option, purely out of respect for Mammon quite 
regardless of God.

But I wonder whether this is empirically likely to be true, given not just the 
nondeductibility of the tax, but also other factors, such as payroll taxes on 
the compensation payment to the employees.  It's not surprising that the 
Justice Department hasn't made this argument, since the Administration has long 
argued (unless I'm mistaken) that large employers won't drop employer-based 
health insurance.  And the Congressional Budget 
Office,http://www.cbo.gov/sites/default/files/cbofiles/ftpdocs/121xx/doc12119/03-30-healthcarelegislation.pdf,
 likewise took the view that only a tiny percentage of employers would drop 
their health insurance, because the legislation leaves in place substantial 
financial advantages for many people to receive insurance coverage through 
their employers, and it provides some new incentives for employers to offer 
insurance coverage to their employees.

Now of course that was in 2011, and perhaps the analysis today would be 
different.  But the CBO's estimates still give me pause.  And if the CBO is 
right, and large employers generally would lose financially -- rather than gain 
from capturing some of the enormous cost savings -- by dropping health 
insurance and adequately compensating employees, then I would think Hobby Lobby 
and others would be in the same position.  The mandate, even enforced as a tax, 
thus would be a substantial burden.

Am I mistaken in this?  Marty, do you have any pointers to studies that support 
your sense of the money flows on this, and contradict what I see