Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-30 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 14, 2010, at 10:17 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Would that FairVote and Rob Richie had listened, they'd have  
learned and they would have modified their strategy to focus on  
deeper and more effective goals. The ultimate goal of FairVote, in  
its foundation, was proportional representation, but they got stuck  
on a political choice as to how to implement it, and then on a  
strategy to faciliate the adoption of that method by using a method  
which is crazy for single-winner, but which is better for  
multiwinner. When one is determining representation, the goal is to  
have one vote from each voter go to one candidate, or to be split  
among candidates, and the goal is to maximize this so that as few  
votes as possible are wasted and the maximum number are represented.


So Later-No-Harm makes sense when finding representatives where  
most votes will find their way. But STV, the general method, is  
still defective, and there are better methods, including ones much  
easier to canvass, so trying to get IRV in order to get the basic  
STV voting system in place was putting the cart before the horse. A  
political error that, I'm sure, looked good at the time.


And what happens with political errors when someone bets their  
career on it? Summary: it gets hard to change course, unless the  
person involved is able to see beyond their own limitations. Not a  
common skill among most political activists, who are trained to be  
bulldogs who don't give up no matter what arguments are tossed at  
them. Debate skills. People are taught how to debate to win, not to  
produce the most sensible result after all has been considered.  
It's too often a piece of an adversarial system, with gladiatorial  
combats, and then the crowd gives thumbs-up or thumbs-down.  
Entertaining, but not particularly efficient for producing  
intelligent and sustainable decisions with a distracted crowd.  
There are much better ways that will work with people-as-they-are.


And it only takes a few people to realize this to start building  
the structures. It is *not* necessary to convince the masses. That  
will come later, after they have examples to look at, which is what  
most people need.


all of the above resonate very closely to what i've been thinking for  
about 10 months.


So my political recommendations are based on what is already known,  
what has been already tried, with only minor variations beyond  
that. Approval voting, one might note the critics state, can  
default to Plurality if most voters vote for their favorite and  
leave it at that. *That's fine.*


no it ain't.  (Plurality is not fine.)

:-)

(it's fine and good for us to have different positions.  i just  
think, and have for decades, that in a multi-candidate race, the  
problems with FPTP are too well known to revert back to that because  
IRV doesn't cut the mustard.)


Most voters, indeed, will vote that way in most elections. So it's  
*harmless* and can be tried, particularly since it is essentially  
no cost to just Count All the Votes, and we should be doing that  
anyway! Does anyone think that it's an irrelevant and worthless  
fact to know how many ballots in Florida 2000 contained votes for  
each of the candidates, regardless of whether or not some were  
overvotes? Even if this information couldn't be used in that  
election because the rules required disregarding overvoted ballots.  
Instead, what's reported is this: overvotes are reported only as  
spoiled ballots. The votes on them are not counted at all. So the  
damage is concealed from us. If a rule has disproportionate impact,  
it can't be seen.


Count All the Votes. And then, I claim, we should use the votes  
that are counted, and political theory generally says that Approval  
Voting, which is simply a matter of Counting All the Votes, is  
quite a good method, superior to plain Plurality, and simply  
defaulting to Plurality if people just vote for their favorite.


i think the folks on the edges want a way to express a preference for  
their guy that will actually count against their fallback guy if the  
race were to become such that's between the two of them.  with  
Approval, they still have to strategize do I vote for both or do I  
vote just for my favorite?  actually (Terry knows about this), in  
Vermont, the State Senate races are sorta weird.  unlike the  
Representatives that have legislative districts drawn (and have a  
single winner for each district), the State Senate candidates run at  
large for the whole county.  being that Burlington is the largest  
city in the state, our county is also the largest, i think.  we have  
6 state Senators and the rules are we can vote for up to 6 on a  
single ballot, and the 6 highest vote getters are elected.  usually a  
party puts out 6 candidates and one might think that they could just  
plug the 6 of their party unless they like to cross over for some  
particular candidate they like.  but if there 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (or is it about Range?)

2010-01-28 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 27, 2010, at 6:55 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 27, 2010, at 11:47 PM, Jameson Quinn wrote:

Without the uneven strategy problem, full-blown Range would be,  
hands down, the best (single-winner) voting system possible


Would you be happy with fixed range ballots (e.g. 0 - 99) or should  
one allow any integer to be used ( -infinity - infinity )?


:-)

If one uses a fixed range should all voters then normalize their  
ratings (worst=0, best=99) or use a narrower scale (e.g. worst=40,  
best=85) if their feelings about the candidates are not very strong?


:-)

implicit to that question is what voters, who bother to come to the  
poll to express their opinions/wishes, would voluntarily reduce their  
influence by narrowing their ranges of approval.  who comes to the  
polls without a desire to support a favorite candidate?  if they do  
not wish to reduce their influence, what will they do with Range?  i  
think nearly every voter will have a 99 and at least one 0.   
otherwise, they leave the poll thinking they threw part of their vote  
away.


Should one determine some reference points for the voters (e.g.  
less than 10 = not accepted, 90 = excellent) to make sure that the  
given ratings are comparable? (this is more important if the range  
is infinite)


:-)

no, i think that if i can think up a negative number with greater  
magnitude than anyone else, i should be able to single-handedly  
scuttle a popular candidate.


Is the sum of votes (or average) really what one wants or should  
one aim at providing about equal results to all, or maybe try to  
keep the worst results to individual voters as high as possible  
(40,40,40 vs. 0,60,60)?


Would there still be electons where we would want to decide based  
on majority and breadth of opposition, or should all elections  
follow the sum of utilities pholosophy?


maybe if we changed it from sum of utility (which is just a scaled  
version of mean of utility) to median of utility.  that might  
help prevent skewing by extremists that will plug their candidate  
with 99 and every opponent with 0.  but if people all do that, Range  
becomes Plurality.


this is the strategy problem of Olympic judges (say of figure skating  
or gymnastics or something with 8 judges holding up cards rating the  
performance).  there is a problem with adding sincere ratings to  
insincere and exaggerated ratings.  *especially* with a secret ballot  
where no one needs to own up to and justify their exaggerated rating.


My point is maybe that if we would get rid of the strategy related  
problems we would be well off but we might then move towards  
solving more detailed problems, performance with sincere votes and  
other problems that are just noise today. On the other hand we do  
have also (almost) strategy free environments/elections/polls today,


with the exception of the strategy called compromising.  that  
happens quite a bit when there are more than two candidates and there  
are at least two candidates that go into the election nearly evenly  
matched in pre-election polls.


it's amazing that anyone touts Range as the most strategy free.  the  
more handles one finds on a control device (think of the ballot as  
such) or the more positions one can set the knobs to, the more one  
has to strategize on how to control it to one's intent.



--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (or is it about Range?)

2010-01-28 Thread Juho

On Jan 28, 2010, at 8:20 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:



On Jan 27, 2010, at 6:55 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 27, 2010, at 11:47 PM, Jameson Quinn wrote:

Without the uneven strategy problem, full-blown Range would be,  
hands down, the best (single-winner) voting system possible


Would you be happy with fixed range ballots (e.g. 0 - 99) or should  
one allow any integer to be used ( -infinity - infinity )?


:-)

If one uses a fixed range should all voters then normalize their  
ratings (worst=0, best=99) or use a narrower scale (e.g. worst=40,  
best=85) if their feelings about the candidates are not very strong?


:-)

implicit to that question is what voters, who bother to come to the  
poll to express their opinions/wishes, would voluntarily reduce  
their influence by narrowing their ranges of approval.  who comes to  
the polls without a desire to support a favorite candidate?  if they  
do not wish to reduce their influence, what will they do with  
Range?  i think nearly every voter will have a 99 and at least one  
0.  otherwise, they leave the poll thinking they threw part of their  
vote away.


Should one determine some reference points for the voters (e.g.  
less than 10 = not accepted, 90 = excellent) to make sure that the  
given ratings are comparable? (this is more important if the range  
is infinite)


:-)

no, i think that if i can think up a negative number with greater  
magnitude than anyone else, i should be able to single-handedly  
scuttle a popular candidate.


Ok, you seem to think that one can not get rid of strategic voting in  
typical (political I guess) elections. Same with normalization and  
probably also exaggeration in Range. (Normalization could also be  
sincere in the sense that the society might recommend all to normalize  
in order to make all votes a bit more equal.) I agree that this is  
very caracteristic to political elections that tend to be more or less  
competitive when arranged by us humans.


(I note that normalization may not be enough. My sincere normalized  
opinion is A=100 B=75 C=0. Then someone introduces intentionally a new  
candidate that others find quite ok but that I strongly dislike.  
Should I vote then A=100 B=95 C=80 D=0? I think they did that on  
purpose! (the normalization tendency can be used strategically) So  
maybe I'll vote A=100 B=75 C=0 D=0 if I don't believe the leading  
candidates are C and D.)




Is the sum of votes (or average) really what one wants or should  
one aim at providing about equal results to all, or maybe try to  
keep the worst results to individual voters as high as possible  
(40,40,40 vs. 0,60,60)?


Would there still be electons where we would want to decide based  
on majority and breadth of opposition, or should all elections  
follow the sum of utilities pholosophy?


maybe if we changed it from sum of utility (which is just a scaled  
version of mean of utility) to median of utility.  that might  
help prevent skewing by extremists that will plug their candidate  
with 99 and every opponent with 0.  but if people all do that, Range  
becomes Plurality.


That would be a good approach in a situation where most voters are  
sincere but we are afraid that some (small subset) of them might be  
strategic.




this is the strategy problem of Olympic judges (say of figure  
skating or gymnastics or something with 8 judges holding up cards  
rating the performance).  there is a problem with adding sincere  
ratings to insincere and exaggerated ratings.  *especially* with a  
secret ballot where no one needs to own up to and justify their  
exaggerated rating.


In ski jumping the practice is that the highest and lowest score will  
not be included in the sum of votes. This approach is somewhere  
between mean and median. Maybe it has some benefits of both. Judges  
come from different major ski jumping countries so often one of the  
judges has a temptation to vote strategically. Votes are public, so a  
strong bias will be visible.




My point is maybe that if we would get rid of the strategy related  
problems we would be well off but we might then move towards  
solving more detailed problems, performance with sincere votes and  
other problems that are just noise today. On the other hand we do  
have also (almost) strategy free environments/elections/polls today,


Strategy free elections are typically non-political. For example if I  
go to restaurant with some of my friends and we will vote what kind of  
giant pizza to order (using Range) then the votes might be sincere.  
One additional reason is that some of my friends might get angry to me  
and leave if my strategic voting gets too obvious. In politics the  
strength of this sincerity encouraging phenomenon is btw quite  
different in different societies.




with the exception of the strategy called compromising.  that  
happens quite a bit when there are more than two candidates and  
there are at least two candidates that go into the 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (or is it about Range? maybe it should be about Condorcet.)

2010-01-28 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 28, 2010, at 3:12 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 8:20 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

...
no, i think that if i can think up a negative number with greater  
magnitude than anyone else, i should be able to single-handedly  
scuttle a popular candidate.


Ok, you seem to think that one can not get rid of strategic voting  
in typical (political I guess) elections.


i think there are ways of not encouraging strategic voting by not  
punishing sincere voting.  i'll defer to Arrow and the common wisdom  
here that ultimately no system completely ditches strategic voting  
under all conceivable conditions.


Is the sum of votes (or average) really what one wants or should  
one aim at providing about equal results to all, or maybe try to  
keep the worst results to individual voters as high as possible  
(40,40,40 vs. 0,60,60)?


Would there still be electons where we would want to decide based  
on majority and breadth of opposition, or should all elections  
follow the sum of utilities pholosophy?


maybe if we changed it from sum of utility (which is just a  
scaled version of mean of utility) to median of utility.  that  
might help prevent skewing by extremists that will plug their  
candidate with 99 and every opponent with 0.  but if people all do  
that, Range becomes Plurality.


That would be a good approach in a situation where most voters are  
sincere but we are afraid that some (small subset) of them might be  
strategic.


i actually don't think it's so good.  i was just trying to point out  
one of the main problems i see with Range.


this is the strategy problem of Olympic judges (say of figure  
skating or gymnastics or something with 8 judges holding up cards  
rating the performance).  there is a problem with adding sincere  
ratings to insincere and exaggerated ratings.  *especially* with a  
secret ballot where no one needs to own up to and justify their  
exaggerated rating.


In ski jumping the practice is that the highest and lowest score  
will not be included in the sum of votes. This approach is  
somewhere between mean and median. Maybe it has some benefits of  
both. Judges come from different major ski jumping countries so  
often one of the judges has a temptation to vote strategically.  
Votes are public, so a strong bias will be visible.


and, again, my point is that with my secret ballot, and my suspicion  
that political opponents may well be voting with exaggerated ratings,  
that *i* would feel pressured to exaggerate *my* preferences and that  
i might expect *any* savvy voter to do the same.  then, if everyone  
does that, the continuous gradation of Range loses its meaning.


My point is maybe that if we would get rid of the strategy  
related problems we would be well off but we might then move  
towards solving more detailed problems, performance with sincere  
votes and other problems that are just noise today. On the other  
hand we do have also (almost) strategy free environments/ 
elections/polls today,


Strategy free elections are typically non-political. For example if  
I go to restaurant with some of my friends and we will vote what  
kind of giant pizza to order (using Range) then the votes might be  
sincere. One additional reason is that some of my friends might get  
angry to me and leave if my strategic voting gets too obvious. In  
politics the strength of this sincerity encouraging phenomenon is  
btw quite different in different societies.


i think that we should expect political opponents to strategize on  
how to defeat their opponents in any society.


with the exception of the strategy called compromising.  that  
happens quite a bit when there are more than two candidates and  
there are at least two candidates that go into the election nearly  
evenly matched in pre-election polls.


it's amazing that anyone touts Range as the most strategy free.   
the more handles one finds on a control device (think of the  
ballot as such) or the more positions one can set the knobs to,  
the more one has to strategize on how to control it to one's intent.


The basic Range strategy is unfortunately present in almost all  
elections,


i don't see how it would be with a simple ranked-order ballot.   
especially, if decided by Condorcet, you cannot exaggerate your  
rankings.  if you like A better than anyone and you like B better  
than C, then there is nothing to be gained by any other ranking than  
ABC.  if you really hate C, you can rank a bunch of other  
candidates you don't care about between B and C.  but it doesn't  
change how the election would work between the candidates A, B, and C.


available to almost all voters and is easy to apply (if we see  
Range as a method where voters are supposed to give their sincere  
(non-normalized or normalized) opinions).



and again, in a response i made long ago to Warren Smith, i think the  
best system is one that assumes that, if there is anything to be  
gained by voting 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (or is it about Range? maybe it should be about Condorcet.)

2010-01-28 Thread Juho

On Jan 28, 2010, at 10:33 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 3:12 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 8:20 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

...
no, i think that if i can think up a negative number with greater  
magnitude than anyone else, i should be able to single-handedly  
scuttle a popular candidate.


Ok, you seem to think that one can not get rid of strategic voting  
in typical (political I guess) elections.


i think there are ways of not encouraging strategic voting by not  
punishing sincere voting.  i'll defer to Arrow and the common wisdom  
here that ultimately no system completely ditches strategic voting  
under all conceivable conditions.


Yes. Arrow's statements of course leaves space for methods that are  
strategy free enough to work in practice as if they were strategy  
free. (I should btw have talked only about not getting rid of the  
interest of voters to vote strategically.)



this is the strategy problem of Olympic judges (say of figure  
skating or gymnastics or something with 8 judges holding up cards  
rating the performance).  there is a problem with adding sincere  
ratings to insincere and exaggerated ratings.  *especially* with a  
secret ballot where no one needs to own up to and justify their  
exaggerated rating.


In ski jumping the practice is that the highest and lowest score  
will not be included in the sum of votes. This approach is  
somewhere between mean and median. Maybe it has some benefits of  
both. Judges come from different major ski jumping countries so  
often one of the judges has a temptation to vote strategically.  
Votes are public, so a strong bias will be visible.


and, again, my point is that with my secret ballot, and my suspicion  
that political opponents may well be voting with exaggerated  
ratings, that *i* would feel pressured to exaggerate *my*  
preferences and that i might expect *any* savvy voter to do the  
same.  then, if everyone does that, the continuous gradation of  
Range loses its meaning.


Yes, strategic voting escalates since it doesn't make sense to anyone  
to let the strategists decide and let the sincere votes to be ignored.



with the exception of the strategy called compromising.  that  
happens quite a bit when there are more than two candidates and  
there are at least two candidates that go into the election nearly  
evenly matched in pre-election polls.


it's amazing that anyone touts Range as the most strategy free.   
the more handles one finds on a control device (think of the  
ballot as such) or the more positions one can set the knobs to,  
the more one has to strategize on how to control it to one's intent.


The basic Range strategy is unfortunately present in almost all  
elections,


i don't see how it would be with a simple ranked-order ballot.   
especially, if decided by Condorcet, you cannot exaggerate your  
rankings.  if you like A better than anyone and you like B better  
than C, then there is nothing to be gained by any other ranking than  
ABC.  if you really hate C, you can rank a bunch of other  
candidates you don't care about between B and C.  but it doesn't  
change how the election would work between the candidates A, B, and C.


Yes, the main rule in Condorcet is that sincere voting is enough.  
Condorcet has also strategic vulnerabilities but in most environments  
one can expect those problems to be so marginal that sincere voting  
will be dominant and is the most practical strategy for all voters.


Juho






Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (or is it about Range? maybe it should be about Condorcet.)

2010-01-28 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 28, 2010, at 5:13 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 10:33 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 3:12 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 8:20 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

...
it's amazing that anyone touts Range as the most strategy free.   
the more handles one finds on a control device (think of the  
ballot as such) or the more positions one can set the knobs to,  
the more one has to strategize on how to control it to one's  
intent.


The basic Range strategy is unfortunately present in almost all  
elections,


i don't see how it would be with a simple ranked-order ballot.   
especially, if decided by Condorcet, you cannot exaggerate your  
rankings.  if you like A better than anyone and you like B better  
than C, then there is nothing to be gained by any other ranking  
than ABC.  if you really hate C, you can rank a bunch of other  
candidates you don't care about between B and C.  but it doesn't  
change how the election would work between the candidates A, B,  
and C.


Yes, the main rule in Condorcet is that sincere voting is enough.  
Condorcet has also strategic vulnerabilities but in most  
environments one can expect those problems to be so marginal that  
sincere voting will be dominant and is the most practical  
strategy for all voters.



again, other than to attempt to throw an election (decided by  
Condorcet rules) into a cycle, i can't think of any situation where  
it would serve any voter's political interests to rank a less  
preferred candidate higher than one that is more preferred.  and,  
it's hard for me to imagine such a strategy serving the voter(s)  
using it, since it could be anyone's guess how the cycle that they  
create gets resolved.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (or is it about Range? maybe it should be about Condorcet.)

2010-01-28 Thread Juho Laatu

On Jan 29, 2010, at 3:36 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:



On Jan 28, 2010, at 5:13 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 10:33 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 3:12 PM, Juho wrote:


On Jan 28, 2010, at 8:20 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

...
it's amazing that anyone touts Range as the most strategy free.   
the more handles one finds on a control device (think of the  
ballot as such) or the more positions one can set the knobs to,  
the more one has to strategize on how to control it to one's  
intent.


The basic Range strategy is unfortunately present in almost all  
elections,


i don't see how it would be with a simple ranked-order ballot.   
especially, if decided by Condorcet, you cannot exaggerate your  
rankings.  if you like A better than anyone and you like B better  
than C, then there is nothing to be gained by any other ranking  
than ABC.  if you really hate C, you can rank a bunch of other  
candidates you don't care about between B and C.  but it doesn't  
change how the election would work between the candidates A, B,  
and C.


Yes, the main rule in Condorcet is that sincere voting is enough.  
Condorcet has also strategic vulnerabilities but in most  
environments one can expect those problems to be so marginal that  
sincere voting will be dominant and is the most practical  
strategy for all voters.



again, other than to attempt to throw an election (decided by  
Condorcet rules) into a cycle, i can't think of any situation where  
it would serve any voter's political interests to rank a less  
preferred candidate higher than one that is more preferred.  and,  
it's hard for me to imagine such a strategy serving the voter(s)  
using it, since it could be anyone's guess how the cycle that they  
create gets resolved.


To be exact, one could also break an already existing cycle for  
strategic reasons (compromise to elect a better winner). And yes, the  
strategies are in most cases difficult to master (due to risk of  
backfiring, no 100% control of the voters, no 100% accurate  
information of the opinions, changing opinions, other strategic  
voters, counterstrategies, losing second preferences of the targets of  
the strategy).


Juho




--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for  
list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-27 Thread Juho

On Jan 27, 2010, at 7:02 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 08:10 PM 1/26/2010, Juho wrote:


The scenario that you described requires some goodwill among the
voters.


That's correct. We seem to imagine that better voting systems will  
produce better results even if people continue to lack goodwill and  
cooperative spirit. It's a fantasy. There are structural changes  
that will encourage the seeking of consensus, but voting methods are  
only a tiny part of that.


I think also the strong tradition of trying to develop methods that  
have as good performance as possible even when voters are competitive  
and strategic is a good and healthy tradition. An ideal method might  
achieve even better results when voters want to cooperate without  
sacrificing the performance with strategic votes. Or if the  
environment is non-competitive then one could use also methods that  
rely on the required sincerity of all voters.




In typical
political environments good poll information including approvals and
ratings is thus a positive thing, but it may still be necessary to
assume that strong competition is not uncommon in the actual election
and prepare for that.


Yes. I do suggest Bucklin. Most voters will bullet vote, it's very  
likely, but, then, use it as a primary in a runoff system, which  
provides a very specific meaning to the lowest approved rank: I  
prefer the election of this candidate to holding a runoff. It's an  
absolute, sincere vote that is strategically maximal! Because that  
is exactly the effect it has, monotonically.


Bucklin + runoff might indeed work better than e.g. plain Approval  
(and plain Plurality of course) (assuming that the increased  
complexity is not seen as a big problem).


Juho







Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-27 Thread Juho

On Jan 27, 2010, at 8:16 AM, Chris Benham wrote:


Juho wrote (26 Jan 2010):

snip
It may well be that this method can be characterized as not fully
Condorcet and Approval strategy added. I'm not quite sure that the
intended idea of mostly Condorcet with core support rewarded (= do
what the IRV core support idea is supposed to do) works well enough to
justify this characterization and the use of this method (when core
support is required). There is however some tendency to reward the
large parties or other core support (as intended) and the behaviour is
quite natural with some more common sets of votes.
snip

Juho,

I don't see the IRV core support idea as a serious part of IRV's  
motivation.


Rather I see it as reasonable propaganda to on the one hand offer some
vague philosophical excuse for not meeting the Condorcet criterion,  
and
on the other reassure those who are wary of too radical a change  
(from Plurality)
that this method will not elect a candidate with very few first  
preferences.




I too believe the requirement of core support is largely used for  
defensive reasons and to make other systems look worse, not that much  
as a true sincere requirement. On the other hand I understand that if  
the current system is a two-party system with single party  
governments, led by one single very powerful person with a long term,  
then in that system those rules tend to have (or at least appear to  
have) about 50% first preference support among the voters, and any  
deviation from this towards having leaders with less first preference  
support and need to cooperate with others in order to be able to rule  
may look like electing too weak candidates. New ways of working may  
look frightening, and if taken directly into use while parts of the  
system remains in the old mode there might indeed be a transition  
period with problems and confusion, even if the end result would be a  
system that eventually will work better. For these reasons I'd like to  
see good definitions of what kind of core support requirements people  
might have in their mind.




The proper criterion that I see it as being most closely positively  
linked to is
Mutual Dominant Third, a weakened version of  Condorcet that says  
that if more
than a third of the voters vote all the members of subset S of  
candidates above
all the non-member candidates and all the members of S pairwise beat  
all

the non-members, then the winner must come from S.


This criterion may well be acceptable to people who are used to  
thinking in terms of Plurality.




Also of course it seeks to put a positive spin on the fact that the  
candidate
with the fewest first preferences can't win, even if that candidate  
is the big

pairwise beats-all winner.

snip
 51: ABC
 41: BCA
 08: CAB

 BA 61.5 - 59,  BC 112.5 - 12,  AC 76.5 - 53

51% voted A as their unique favourite and 59% voted A above B, and
yet B wins.

Yes, and I believe there are more criteria that the method fails. We
should however from some point of view be happy since the method
elected B that seems to have 92% core support (maybe this is how I
defined core support in this method).
snip

Defining as you do core support as approval, what is your  
objection to

simpler methods that don't allow ranking among unapproved candidates
(and so just interpret ranking above bottom as approval) such as the
Smith//Approval(ranking) method I endorse?


That is another working method that also at some level rewards core  
support (=approvals). I don't object the method. My first concerns are  
maybe in the direction that you mentioned, methods that don't allow  
ranking among unapproved candidates. It sounds a bit problematic if  
the voters of the losing side would generally not take any position  
on which one of the candidates of the winning side should win (if  
they choose not to rank them in order to show their non-approval of  
them). That might lead to not electing a candidate that all like but a  
candidate that the winning side internally likes (but that could be  
the worst candidate from the point of view of the losing side voters).




Or if you think that it is justified for a candidate with a very big  
approval

score to beat a majority favourite with less approval, why not simply
promote the plain Approval method?


I'm actually not taking any position on if core support should be  
required = just saying what one could do if (this particular kind of)  
core support is required. A two-party system is based on heavy use of  
core support but in a genuine multiparty environment it is more  
difficult for me to find reasons to explicitly require strong core  
support to be present.


The first reason in my head why I don't feel like promoting Approval  
as a good general purpose single winner method for all needs is that  
although it does pretty good work in finding a widely approved  
candidate (when that is what the society wants) when there are two  
leading candidates it 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-27 Thread Jameson Quinn
2010/1/26 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a...@lomaxdesign.com




 The typical error is in assuming some strategic faction which votes
 sensibly, when everyone else votes in a way that they will regret if they
 discover the result they cause.


You can't study history for two minutes without finding significant groups
of people (that is, ~5% fractions, not everyone else) behaving in ways
they come to regret later. This is unavoidable human nature, and
acknowledging it is no error.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-27 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 08:51 AM 1/27/2010, Jameson Quinn wrote:
2010/1/26 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax 
mailto:a...@lomaxdesign.coma...@lomaxdesign.com


The typical error is in assuming some strategic faction which 
votes sensibly, when everyone else votes in a way that they will 
regret if they discover the result they cause.


You can't study history for two minutes without finding significant 
groups of people (that is, ~5% fractions, not everyone else) 
behaving in ways they come to regret later. This is unavoidable 
human nature, and acknowledging it is no error.


Now, is the voting system supposed to protect them from their stupidity?

We were not talking about a minor faction voting that way, but half 
of the two largest, with 20% of the vote, in the example Mr. Quinn 
created, the total faction being 40%. The opposing 40% vote 
*normally!*, all of them. The vote cast by this 20% faction 
effectively says I have very little preference between Bore and 
Cush. (It's 1/5 vote!) So if the voting system interprets their vote 
that way, we are supposed to blame the system?


There is supposedly a Moral issue here, the idea that we are not 
supposed to reward dishonesty. But a vote is never dishonest, it is 
an action, tossing a weight or weights in a balance or balances, 
intending to swing the balances some way. It's not a sentiment, and 
it is not a statement under some binding rule of honesty that could 
be defined. Reversing preference is more arguable, perhaps, but this 
still applies. Moral responsibility lies in the consequences of the 
actions, or at least in what we could anticipate from them. Hence, if 
the 20% believes that their vote was foolish, the responsibility for 
that lies with them.


Look, I would not dump full-blown Range on an electorate. I'm 
proposing Bucklin, which would allow ranking in a way that makes it 
roughly equivalent to rating, with the three ranks meaning -- and it 
might say that right on the ballot -- Favorite, Preferred, and 
Also Approved. I prefer to see this as the primary in a runoff 
system, so that Also Approved has a very clear preference meaning: 
I prefer to see these candidates elected to a runoff being held. 
Later-No-Harm is important to you? Fine. Just vote for your favorite. 
If your favorite gets a majority, done. If not, then, if your 
favorite is a leader by the criteria used to determine runoff 
candidates, you will presumably vote for your favorite again. If your 
favorite doesn't make it, you will still have your option to cast a 
vote indicating preference again.


This isn't *difficult.* But it leads, later, after there is more 
experience, to using a Range Ballot to accomplish the same thing, 
only with a bit more subtlety, and the Range ballot would start with 
only one more rank: Preferred to the worst. The original ballot can 
be analyzed as Range 4, with a vote of 1 missing, the values are 4, 
3, 2, 0. The extended ballot adds the 1. Initially, that might not 
even be used to determine a winner, but would be used to collect 
preference information from voters who don't support a winner. It 
might then be used to make somewhat better choices for runoffs. It 
would never be considered approval of such a candidate, indeed, it is 
disapproval. Following basic democratic procedures, a winner would 
never be declared in a primary with less than a majority, but if, 
after study of such elections and runoffs, it is determined that 
there is no significant risk of reversal in a runoff with a less 
stringent standard, that's fine with me; compromises are made in the 
name of efficiency when the loss in efficiency is great enough to 
warrant the loss in full confidence.


Note that in the election described, by the votes, there would be a 
majority winner if we assume that 80% is approval



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-27 Thread Jameson Quinn
2010/1/27 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a...@lomaxdesign.com

 At 08:51 AM 1/27/2010, Jameson Quinn wrote:

 2010/1/26 Abd ul-Rahman Lomax mailto:a...@lomaxdesign.com
 a...@lomaxdesign.com


 The typical error is in assuming some strategic faction which votes
 sensibly, when everyone else votes in a way that they will regret if they
 discover the result they cause.

 You can't study history for two minutes without finding significant groups
 of people (that is, ~5% fractions, not everyone else) behaving in ways
 they come to regret later. This is unavoidable human nature, and
 acknowledging it is no error.


 Now, is the voting system supposed to protect them from their stupidity?


It isn't necessarily stupidity. It could be ethics, or genuine lack of
available information.

It's not just protecting them. It's protecting the majority of which they
form a part.

And every other serious voting system would do so.

So yes.



 We were not talking about a minor faction voting that way,


My example had showed how even large advantages could, theoretically, be
overruled by uneven strategy. But I keep insisting, and you keep not
hearing, that that's just to illustrate a point. For something more
realistic, consider my example as the middle 10%, with 45% bullet voters on
either side. In that case, 49% strategic voters are overcoming 45% strategic
and 6% unstrategic voters. It's easy to change the numbers so that even 47%
strategic voters (with 2% unstrategic ones on their side) can overcome the
same odds, and still be overturning the true Range winner.



 

 Look, I would not dump full-blown Range on an electorate.


OK, I guess you do get it. So why do you keep arguing with me?

Without the uneven strategy problem, full-blown Range would be, hands
down, the best (single-winner) voting system possible, and the EM list's
days would be numbered until we all just agreed on that and went home.
Because of this problem, Range is not perfect, and there is still a lot to
talk about here.

Jameson Quinn

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-27 Thread Juho

On Jan 27, 2010, at 11:47 PM, Jameson Quinn wrote:

Without the uneven strategy problem, full-blown Range would be,  
hands down, the best (single-winner) voting system possible


Would you be happy with fixed range ballots (e.g. 0 - 99) or should  
one allow any integer to be used ( -infinity - infinity )?


If one uses a fixed range should all voters then normalize their  
ratings (worst=0, best=99) or use a narrower scale (e.g. worst=40,  
best=85) if their feelings about the candidates are not very strong?


Should one determine some reference points for the voters (e.g. less  
than 10 = not accepted, 90 = excellent) to make sure that the given  
ratings are comparable? (this is more important if the range is  
infinite)


Is the sum of votes (or average) really what one wants or should one  
aim at providing about equal results to all, or maybe try to keep the  
worst results to individual voters as high as possible (40,40,40 vs.  
0,60,60)?


Would there still be electons where we would want to decide based on  
majority and breadth of opposition, or should all elections follow the  
sum of utilities pholosophy?


My point is maybe that if we would get rid of the strategy related  
problems we would be well off but we might then move towards solving  
more detailed problems, performance with sincere votes and other  
problems that are just noise today. On the other hand we do have also  
(almost) strategy free environments/elections/polls today, so our  
selection of decision making (or utility measuring) algorithms should  
cover also them.


Juho






Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-26 Thread Juho

On Jan 26, 2010, at 4:43 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 07:22 PM 1/25/2010, Juho wrote:


There are many (working) uses for an approval cutoff in ranked
ballots. But on the other hand they may add complexity and confusion
and not add anything essential. = Careful consideration needed.


Only a voting systems theorist who is not a parliamentarian or  
familiar with the principles of parliamentary traditions, essential  
in direct democracy, would think approval not relevant. Approval is  
Yes/No on the series of possible choices. It's fundamental,  
actually, and compromises with this are *never* made in direct  
democracies, they are only made in the name of efficiency in large- 
scale elections.


I referred only to approval cutoffs as additional components in  
existing methods.





Bucklin does that, basically, by only considering approval votes,
but it sets up a declining approval cutoff, typically in three
batches, loosely named as Favorite, Preferred, and Approved. I've
suggested that in a runoff voting situation, majority required,
Approved has a very specific meaning: it means I would prefer to
see this candidate elected over holding a runoff election. Voters,
then, by what candidates they choose to approve given their overall
understanding of election possibilities, will sincerely vote this.
It makes no sense not to.


Bucklin is a bit simpler.


Simpler than what? The proposed method? Sure.


By definition, range methods put extra weight on first preferences,
if the voter chooses to express the first preference exclusively, as
does Bucklin, at least in the first round.


Range is also designed to elect candidates with no core support, e.g.
one that gets 60% of the points from all voters while all others have
only limited amount of strong support and no support from the rest.
IRV puts always main weight on first preferences (among the remaining
candidates).


Yes. However, designed to elect candidates with no core support is  
an overstatement. It certainly is not designed for that, but it  
allows it. It's pretty unlikely, eh?


Yes, but desirable if one wants to respect the basic philosophy of sum  
of ratings.


The most common response to this claim when it comes from FairVote  
is,Really, even the candidate and her mother prefer someone else?  
And when there really is a problem with core support, it comes down  
to, usually, center squeeze, and the compromise winner is, in fact,  
quite strong in first preference votes, but merely ends up, in a  
three-way race, in third place, and not by a large margin. Not at  
all no core support.


Appeasing the core support criterion is a very bad idea, rewarding  
partisan affiliation without sound reason for it; the only arguments  
I've seen for it that carry any weight are arguments that core  
support is necessary for good governance, which is not entirely  
incorrect, but which doesn't counterbalance the danger of serious  
social division. Remember that the Nazi Party in Germany had core  
support. Mmmm, did that help them govern? Sure it did! But good  
governance? No, not at all, I certainly hope we will agree. Any  
core support criterion pushes results away from true majority- 
supported results toward domination by the largest faction. Which,  
of course, then encourages a two-party system, at best.


There is no good definition of core support. It is quite possible that  
there are elections where core support or weight on first preferences  
is a desirable feature. But it is hard to discuss and judge as long as  
that feature is not well specified (I don't consider the operational  
definition as derived from how IRV works to be a proper definition).


Juho









Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-26 Thread Juho


On Jan 26, 2010, at 6:07 AM, Chris Benham wrote:


Juho  wrote (25 Jan 2010):

I reply to myself since I want to present one possible simple method
that combines Condorcet and added weight to first preferences
(something that IRV offers in its own peculiar way).

Let's add an approval cutoff in the Condorcet ballots. The first
approach could be to accept only winners that have some agreed amount
of approvals. But I'll skip that approach and propose something
softer. A clear approval cutoff sounds too black and white to me
(unless there is already some agreed level of approval that must be
met).

The proposal is simply to add some more strength to opinions that
cross the approval cutoff. Ballot ABCD would be counted as 1 point
to pairwise comparisons AB and CD but some higher number of points
(e.g. 1.5) to comparisons AC, AD, BC and BD. This would introduce
some approval style strategic opportunities in the method but basic
ranking would stay as sincere as it was. I don't believe the approval
related strategic problems would be as bad in this method as in
Approval itself.
snip

The  some higher number of points (e.g. 1.5)  looks arbitrary


Yes it is (with the intention to allow the required amount of core  
support to be adjusted), just like the whole method is (somewhat ad  
hoc). I'd like to have a good definition of what the target of core  
support and weight on first preferences is. That would make it  
possible to discuss the benefits and problems better. Now the proposed  
method is just simple, it may work well enough in real elections, and  
offers one approach to emphasizing core support.



and results
in the method failing Majority Favourite, never mind Condorcet etc.

51: ABC
41: BCA
08: CAB

BA 61.5 - 59,  BC 112.5 - 12,  AC 76.5 - 53

51% voted A as their unique favourite and 59% voted A above B, and  
yet B wins.


Yes, and I believe there are more criteria that the method fails. We  
should however from some point of view be happy since the method  
elected B that seems to have 92% core support (maybe this is how I  
defined core support in this method).


Those 51% that approved both A and B must be quite happy with electing  
B since they indicated that B is approved (has their core support).  
If some of them strongly think that A should have won instead of B  
then they applied the Approval strategy poorly (= should have approved  
A only in a situation where A and B are the main competitors).


Those 59% that preferred A over B include also the C supporters. They  
should have approved also A to make the chances of A winning B bigger.  
Thus also the C supporters didn't use the traditional Approval  
strategy properly (assuming that they strongly want A to win B).


The basic assumption thus is that the voter given rankings are mainly  
sincere but large part of the approvals may be strategic. In real life  
the strategic incentives are probably not as strong as in this example.


It may well be that this method can be characterized as not fully  
Condorcet and Approval strategy added. I'm not quite sure that the  
intended idea of mostly Condorcet with core support rewarded (= do  
what the IRV core support idea is supposed to do) works well enough to  
justify this characterization and the use of this method (when core  
support is required). There is however some tendency to reward the  
large parties or other core support (as intended) and the behaviour is  
quite natural with some more common sets of votes. See example below.


45: ABC
10: BA=C
45: CBA

This is an example with a centrist Condorcet winner. In Condorcet B  
would win. In the proposed method the core support of B is not  
sufficient. A=C 67.5 - 67.5,  AB 82.5 - 60,  CB 82.5 - 60.


If the number of votes would be changed to 42: ABC, 16: BA=C, 42:  
CBA that would be enough to make B the winner with the chosen  
factor 1.5 (16 = sufficient amount of core support).


Juho





Chris Benham


  
__
Yahoo!7: Catch-up on your favourite Channel 7 TV shows easily,  
legally, and for free at PLUS7. www.tv.yahoo..com.au/plus7





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-26 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:04 AM 1/26/2010, Juho wrote:

On Jan 26, 2010, at 4:43 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 07:22 PM 1/25/2010, Juho wrote:


There are many (working) uses for an approval cutoff in ranked
ballots. But on the other hand they may add complexity and confusion
and not add anything essential. = Careful consideration needed.


Only a voting systems theorist who is not a parliamentarian or
familiar with the principles of parliamentary traditions, essential
in direct democracy, would think approval not relevant. Approval is
Yes/No on the series of possible choices. It's fundamental,
actually, and compromises with this are *never* made in direct
democracies, they are only made in the name of efficiency in large- 
scale elections.


I referred only to approval cutoffs as additional components in
existing methods.


My point is that approval is a separate issue from ranking, and 
it's actually a crucial issue in multiple-choice decision-making in 
general. I've seen, after an approval poll in a context where the 
first preference of most members was about 70% for one option, but an 
approval polls showed little more than that as approval for that 
option, but 99% approval for an alternative, a motion to adopt the 
alternative, seconded and passed with no dissent at all, unanimity. 
The only way to discover a situation like this is some later poll, 
repeated election. Had the original poll been an actual election, 
choosing the highest approval would have, in fact, implemented the 
will of the majority. Usually. That's why approval voting is 
reasonable, but also why runoff elections or similar tests are 
sometimes needed. Note that, in a situation where they already knew 
(this was show-of-hands voting, and the status quo voting was first) 
that they had a strong majority, the 70% nevertheless approved also 
the alternative, probably based on the thorough discussion that had 
preceded the poll. They understood the depth of feeling behind the 
opposition to the status quo, and, seeking the common welfare, which 
depends on organizational unity, they allowed the other option to 
prevail by approving it as well.


In repeated polling, approval is an excellent way to rapidly seek a 
majority; in contentious issues without adequate deliberation, such 
polls may start out as largely bullet-voted, but as the process 
continues, approvals will be added, and some prior approvals might be 
dropped (representing an actual change in preference order, a 
phenomenon possible in repeated elections and obviously impossible 
with a single-ballot. In the situation I described, many of those 
preferring the status quo -- which had stood for maybe forty years -- 
had said, at first, over my dead body. I'd call that strong 
disapproval, eh? But, after discussion and expression of many 
different member sentiments, those members obviously changed their minds.)



Yes. However, designed to elect candidates with no core support is
an overstatement. It certainly is not designed for that, but it
allows it. It's pretty unlikely, eh?


Yes, but desirable if one wants to respect the basic philosophy of sum
of ratings.


Right. Setting aside the issue of using averages, which I consider 
foolish as a practical proposal at this time, but which, when we get 
real Range elections happening, sum of votes obviously maximizes 
expressed expected satisfaction with the various outcomes. Range 
voting is interesting precisely because it bases outcomes on a metric 
for election performance, and the only issue is a lot of hot air 
about strategic voting in Range.


My view on this is simple: strategic voting in Range expresses real 
preference strength. In other words, it's an oxymoron, created by an 
assumption that when a voter exaggerates, the voter doesn't really 
care that much. But how much we care always depends on our perception 
of realities.


If a range outcome benefits me to the tune of $100, and another costs 
me $100, other things being equal, what's my preference strength 
between these. We can assign an absolute value ($200) to the 
preference strength, but that does not determine a sensible Range 
vote. If those are the only two options, the vote strength I will 
exercise is 100% between them. But say there are two more options, 
but all of them are considered by me to be impossible, the other 
voters won't support them. Suppose with one of these options, I gain 
$1000, and with another, I lose $1000. Does this change my sincere vote?


I say no. But with unlimited Range, sure, I'd honestly state the 
actual utilities, as long as the analysis made sense (as with a 
Clarke tax). With normalized range, which is what we ordinarily see, 
I will express, reasonably, my utilities within a truncated set, 
where unrealistic alternatives are excluded. I have called this 
magnification, because a sincere vote represents only the 
spectrum including realistic candidates. Which then indicates, with 
Approval, an obvious and oft-suggested 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-26 Thread Kevin Venzke
Hi,

--- En date de : Mar 26.1.10, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a...@lomaxdesign.com a 
écrit :
 Range voting is interesting
 precisely because it bases outcomes on a metric for election
 performance, and the only issue is a lot of hot air about
 strategic voting in Range.
 
 My view on this is simple: strategic voting in Range
 expresses real preference strength. In other words, it's an
 oxymoron, created by an assumption that when a voter
 exaggerates, the voter doesn't really care that much. But
 how much we care always depends on our perception of
 realities.

Well, this is just a change of terminology. You can say that Range 
relatively has strategic incentive to exaggerate, or you can say
that in Range the sincere vote is relatively dependent on voters'
perceptions of which candidates are viable. Either way this will be
often be regarded as a disadvantage.

Kevin Venzke


  

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-26 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 08:10 PM 1/26/2010, Juho wrote:


The scenario that you described requires some goodwill among the
voters.


That's correct. We seem to imagine that better voting systems will 
produce better results even if people continue to lack goodwill and 
cooperative spirit. It's a fantasy. There are structural changes that 
will encourage the seeking of consensus, but voting methods are only 
a tiny part of that.



 If the competition is really strong then one could expect the
70% of the voters not to even mention the 99% approved candidate in
the polls if they already know that they have 70% majority behind
their first preference.


That's right, if they don't care about alienating 30% of the members 
of the organization, an organization that breaks down and becomes 
dysfunctional if people fight with each other and fail to respect the 
need for unity.



On the other hand the availability of reliable poll information may
reduce the competitive spirit of the election.


What you do is to poll, and allowing approval polling is simple, 
nobody even though of suggesting that people only vote once in the 
show of hands. The question wasn't a preference question, it was 
would you consider this choice acceptable. The poll wasn't going to 
decide anything, and this was a group of people whose culture 
facilitated and encouraged complete honesty, and the whole thing 
would become a stupid waste of time without the honesty, it was 
fundamental and crucial, or even more than a stupid waste of time, 
positively harmful.



 Some part of strategic
voting and strong competitiveness is based on the fear of unknown and
lack of understanding of the viewpoints of the others. If all take a
defensive attitude from the start and paint all their competitors with
dark colours then there may never be any consensus.


Right.


 In typical
political environments good poll information including approvals and
ratings is thus a positive thing, but it may still be necessary to
assume that strong competition is not uncommon in the actual election
and prepare for that.


Yes. I do suggest Bucklin. Most voters will bullet vote, it's very 
likely, but, then, use it as a primary in a runoff system, which 
provides a very specific meaning to the lowest approved rank: I 
prefer the election of this candidate to holding a runoff. It's an 
absolute, sincere vote that is strategically maximal! Because that is 
exactly the effect it has, monotonically.



Voters may also understand that a society that makes consensus
decisions may be a better place to live in than a society where the
current majority always ignores the minorities. And people may vote
for parties that support this approach. But also here, it may still be
wise to allow the majority to decide when consensus decisions (that
cover also the needs of the other side) will be made. In a way we are
talking about a benevolent majority and the growth of a society
towards away from a conflict driven mode.


Majority rule is a crucial foundation for democracy. But if the 
majority is stupid, it can wreck the place, and everyone is in the 
minority from time to time. Seeking supermajority approval actually 
helps everyone, long-term, but there is a tradeoff with efficiency.



Yes, the good part of Range is in the satisfaction measurements. I
think the strategy problems are very real in many environments, not
just hot air. So one must be careful with Range.


The typical error is in assuming some strategic faction which votes 
sensibly, when everyone else votes in a way that they will regret if 
they discover the result they cause.


[...]

There is a natural incentive to the two largest groupings to promote
this kind of polarization. And a two-party system is a demonstration
that such systems may also work reasonably well in practice.


Sometimes, when the social contract is strong and the distance 
between the two parties is actually not large (i.e., Tweedledum and 
Tweedledee might be a bit of a good thing!), it works, but sometimes 
it leads to civil war and genocide, when the polarization becomes too great 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-25 Thread Juho
] IRV vs Plurality


On Jan 13, 2010, at 9:14 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


it still is a curiosity to me how, historically, some leaders and
proponents of election reform thunked up the idea to have a ranked-
order ballot and then took that good idea and married it to the IRV
protocol.  with the 200 year old Condorcet idea in existence, why
would they do that?


1) The basic idea of IRV is in some sense natural. It is like a  
street
fight. The weakest players are regularly kicked out and they must  
give

up. I'm not saying that this would lead to good results but at least
this game is understandable to most people. Condorcet on the other
hand is more like a mathematical equation, and the details of the  
most

complex Condorcet variants may be too much for most voters. Here I'm
not saying that each voter (and not even each legislator) should
understand all the details of their voting system. The basic  
Condorcet

winner rule is however a simple enough principle to be explained to
all. But it may be that IRV is easier to market (to the legislators
and voters) from this point of view.

2) IRV is easier to count manually. Condorcet gets quite tedious to
count manually when the number of candidates and voters goes up. One
can use some tricks and shortcuts to speed up manual Condorcet
counting but IRV probably still beats it from this point of view.
Manual counting was the only way to count for a long time. Nowadays  
we

have computers and Condorcet tabulation should thus be no problem at
all (at least in places where computers are available). But this is
one reason why IRV has taken an early lead.

3) Large parties are typically in a key role when electoral reforms
are made. Election method experts within those parties may well have
found out that IRV tends to favour large parties. In addition to
trying to improve the society the best way they can, political  
parties

and people within them also tend to think that they are the ones who
are right and therefore the society would benefit of just them being
in power and getting more votes and more seats. The parties and their
representatives may also have other more selfish drivers behind their
interest to grab as large share of the power as possible :-). IRV  
thus

seems to maintain the power of the current strongest players better
than Condorcet does, and that may mean some bias towards IRV.

4) The problems of different election methods may appear only  
later. A

superficial understanding of IRV reveals first its positive features.
Like in Burlington the negative features may be understood only after
something negative happens in real elections. This applies also to
Condorcet. On that side one may however live in the hope that the
problems are rare enough and not easy to take advantage of so that
sincere voting and good results would be dominant. The point is that
IRV may be taken into use first (see other points above and below)
without understanding what problems might emerge later. And once it
has been taken into use it may well stay in use for a long time
(electoral reforms are not made every year, people have already  
gotten

used to the method, having to change the method could be seen by the
society/legislators as a failure/embarrassment, and people/parties  
who
were elected based on those rules and are strong in that system may  
be

reluctant to change the rules).

5) Both IRV and Condorcet have some weak spots that can be attacked.
As you point out the weak spots of IRV may well be worse than those  
of

Condorcet methods (for most typical use cases in politics). Different
problems may have different weight in different political
environments. For example in countries with strong two-party  
tradition

and single party government some Condorcet properties like the
possibility of electing candidates that do not have strong first
preference support in the ballots may work against it (both in the
case that one does not want the system to change and in the case that
one wants to renew the system). Also strategic voting and fraud
related problems (like later no harm, burial, precinct counting) may
be seen in different light in different societies, e.g. in countries
where strategic voting is the norm vs. in ones where sincere voting  
is

the norm. One may thus have/develop points of view where Condorcet
looks worse than IRV (I guess it could also be worse for some uses in
some societies from some points of view).

Juho


P.S. One more reason is that Condorcet promoters seem to be lazier
that IRV promoters :-). Condorcet has made some progress in the
academic circles but not yet in politics.









Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for  
list info





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for  
list info



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-25 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 07:22 PM 1/25/2010, Juho wrote:


There are many (working) uses for an approval cutoff in ranked
ballots. But on the other hand they may add complexity and confusion
and not add anything essential. = Careful consideration needed.


Only a voting systems theorist who is not a parliamentarian or 
familiar with the principles of parliamentary traditions, essential 
in direct democracy, would think approval not relevant. Approval is 
Yes/No on the series of possible choices. It's fundamental, actually, 
and compromises with this are *never* made in direct democracies, 
they are only made in the name of efficiency in large-scale elections.



Bucklin does that, basically, by only considering approval votes,
but it sets up a declining approval cutoff, typically in three
batches, loosely named as Favorite, Preferred, and Approved. I've
suggested that in a runoff voting situation, majority required,
Approved has a very specific meaning: it means I would prefer to
see this candidate elected over holding a runoff election. Voters,
then, by what candidates they choose to approve given their overall
understanding of election possibilities, will sincerely vote this.
It makes no sense not to.


Bucklin is a bit simpler.


Simpler than what? The proposed method? Sure.


By definition, range methods put extra weight on first preferences,
if the voter chooses to express the first preference exclusively, as
does Bucklin, at least in the first round.


Range is also designed to elect candidates with no core support, e.g.
one that gets 60% of the points from all voters while all others have
only limited amount of strong support and no support from the rest.
IRV puts always main weight on first preferences (among the remaining
candidates).


Yes. However, designed to elect candidates with no core support is 
an overstatement. It certainly is not designed for that, but it 
allows it. It's pretty unlikely, eh? The most common response to this 
claim when it comes from FairVote is,Really, even the candidate and 
her mother prefer someone else? And when there really is a problem 
with core support, it comes down to, usually, center squeeze, and the 
compromise winner is, in fact, quite strong in first preference 
votes, but merely ends up, in a three-way race, in third place, and 
not by a large margin. Not at all no core support.


Appeasing the core support criterion is a very bad idea, rewarding 
partisan affiliation without sound reason for it; the only arguments 
I've seen for it that carry any weight are arguments that core 
support is necessary for good governance, which is not entirely 
incorrect, but which doesn't counterbalance the danger of serious 
social division. Remember that the Nazi Party in Germany had core 
support. Mmmm, did that help them govern? Sure it did! But good 
governance? No, not at all, I certainly hope we will agree. Any core 
support criterion pushes results away from true majority-supported 
results toward domination by the largest faction. Which, of course, 
then encourages a two-party system, at best.



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-23 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Kathy Dopp wrote:

James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.
That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.


As a note: some methods (most discussed here, actually) also permit both 
truncation and equal-ranking. If one takes that into account, the 
formulas become more complex still.


Yet, on another level, this may not really matter. On the one hand, if 
there'll ever just be a few candidates, the amount of information to 
transmit is managable. On the other, setting a hard limit to, say, no 
more than 5 candidates may participate in this election is rather 
inelegant, and I would say, unfair, and if the potential number of 
candidates can grow to any number, it doesn't matter what formula is 
being used as long as it's superpolynomial (and so the values grow very 
large very quickly). Truncation or no truncation, equal rank or not, the 
number of unique orderings grow in that manner.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-23 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 09:52 PM 1/22/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

now remember in the case we're discussing here, there is only two
candidates.  again, what consequence to the outcome of the election
(that is, who of A or B wins) occurs whether a ballot is marked
A (and B is last by default) or is marked AB?

there is none.


If there are only two possible choices, that's the case. However, in 
fully democratic elections, the only case where there are only two 
choices is election by motion. The question is of the form of 
Resolved: that A be elected to the office. Yes/No.


I will be putting together a document that compiles relevant rules 
and discussion from Robert's Rules of Order as it relates to voting, 
elections, ballots, and particularly preferential voting, because I 
consider an understanding of deliberative election process as 
essential to understanding voting system optimization. It is far more 
sophisticated than any voting system on the table, and the only 
problem is one of efficiency. While it is a method of election, in 
the general sense, it has been neglected because it is very difficult 
to study. It is not deterministic from a single set of preference 
profiles, even if they include preference strength information.


In public elections where write-in votes are allowed (which is so 
much the norm in the U.S. that it is preposterous to neglect it, and 
sometimes write-in candidates win), there are actually a practically 
unlimited number of optional votes. That *normally* write-in votes 
are largely irrelevant does not change this. The methods must allow 
for the possibility. So, as a compromise, canvassing methods may 
neglect the possible variety of write-in votes, and canvass them as 
if for a single candidate. But, then, if the number of votes for the 
single write-in candidate, were they all one candidate, possibly 
affect the result, it becomes necessary to count and report those 
individual write-in votes. I have not detailed how this would be 
done, and it is possible that, depending on conditions, it could be 
made more efficient than simply reporting every vote. But in some 
cases, reporting every vote might be necessary!



i'm not going to discuss this any more with Abd, because he's not a
straight shooter, but James, if you want to get into this, it's
pretty much cut and dried from the POV of Information Theory (a.la.
Claude Shannon).


This conclusion depends on understanding the situation to which the 
theory is being applied. That's what Robert misses. He makes 
simplifying assumptions without being aware that these assumptions 
are not applicable in the general case, but he does not specify the 
assumptions, nor does he take note of them when they are specified by 
others, including me, he merely concludes that I'm not a straight 
shooter, which would imply some deceptive intent, but he has adduced 
no evidence of that, merely his idea that I am wrong, which he has 
repeated over and over as if that would establish it as a fact, 
rather than a detailed examination of the evidence and arguments. His 
privilege, here.



1.  there are three eligible candidates, A, B, and C.
2.  a particular voter has A as his/her first preference.
3.  the same voter has B as the second preference.
4.  the same voter has C as the last preference.


The question is whether or not the vote ABC is different from AB, 
whether or not the difference is worth reporting, or, stronger, 
necessary to report. And that depends on details of the rules, which 
Robert has neither stated nor accepted, and he has denied, without 
evidence, comments that did specify exceptions to the rules he 
proposes, -- not made-up, but real-world exceptions.


I'll give the most notable: if a majority is required for election, 
and according to accepted parliamentary procedure, majority means 
more than half of all non-black ballots cast. Whether or not a 
candidate is eligible or not is irrelevant! Robert has adduced a 
preference profile, but has not specified one critical piece of 
information, in determining the relevance of an ABC vote compared 
to AB. Is the voter willing to accept the result of the election of 
C, or would the voter prefer that the election fail? In short, does 
the voter approve of the election of C? We cannot tell that from the 
raw preference profile without approval information.


I gave examples -- and analyzed Robert's examples -- where the two 
votes are different in consequence.


Now, let's narrow the question, being aware that we are now more 
narrowly specifying it. If the election is election by plurality, 
does the third preference vote make a practical difference? Not in 
determining the result, but it is still important in assessing 
election quality, and examples could be shown where this is important 
as public information. There are rarely IRV elections which are by 
plurality, where, if the counting is continued one more step, the 
election would be by a majority. Even though this is 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:25 AM
 On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
 
  N Unique Preference Profiles
  2 4
  3 15
  ...
 
  then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you 
 ostensibly need 
  4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.
 
 
  If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique  
  preference profiles are:
  A   
  B   
  AB 
  BA
 
 
 
 what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between  
 A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one  
 marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses  
 ranked ballots?

In terms of preference profiles the question is completely irrelevant.  A 
and AB are two different preference profiles.  So
the possible numbers of preference profiles for given numbers of candidates 
are, I think, correctly stated in the table in my
earlier post.

How the STV counting rules handle the two preference profiles A and AB is 
a different matter.  Some STV counting rules handle
these two profiles identically.  But for some other STV counting rules the 
profiles A and AB are handled differently.  This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes to the 
bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated differently 
from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable (exhausted)', but the 
AB ballot would be transferred to A.

This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean it has not 
been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,
sadly, Scotland.  It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my 
vote could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible place, e.g. 
12th out of 12 candidates.  Following on from the
concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency voting, as 
in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances will her 
vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter end rule 
undermines this.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy
I think my post made clear that I was referring only to preference profiles.  
I was not dealing with the situation where some
artificial, and highly undesirable, restriction had been placed on the numbers 
of rankings the voters could mark.

I think my comments about the counting procedure adopted in Minneapolis should 
have indicated that I am well aware of the
restrictions that can be imposed.  But note that in Minneapolis the restriction 
was an artificial one imposed by the certified
counting machines available for use in the precincts.  There is nothing in the 
Minneapolis Election Ordinance that imposes such a
restriction.  So when Minneapolis can obtain certified counting machines that 
can deal with fully ranked ballots, there will be no
such restriction in practice.

James

 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:43 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)
 
 
 James,
 
 Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters 
 are allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an 
 election contest. That may be true in Australia, but is not 
 true in the US where typically voters are allowed to rank up 
 to only three candidates.
 
 I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n 
 candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV 
 that I wrote a year or two ago:
 
 Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting 
 http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantR
 unoffVotingFlaws.pdf
 
 
 Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula, 
 etc. here I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc 
 linked above.
 
 Cheers,
 
 Kathy
 
 
 
  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
  I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the 
  numbers of possible unique preference profiles for 
 increasing numbers 
  of candidates (N) as follows:
 
  N       Unique Preference Profiles
  2       4
  3       15
  4       64
  5       325
  6       1,956
  7       13,699
  8       109,600
  9       986,409
  10      9,864,100
  11      108,505,111
  12      1,302,061,344
  13      16,926,797,485
  14      236,975,164,804
  15      3,554,627,472,075
  16      56,874,039,553,216
  17      966,858,672,404,689
  18      17,403,456,103,284,400
  19      330,665,665,962,404,000
  20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000
 
 
  Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible 
  number of unique preference profiles will be limited by the 
 number of 
  voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 
 candidates, the 
  maximum possible number of preference profiles would be 
 10,000 and not 
  1,302,061,344.
 
  In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even 
  lower, as significant numbers of voters would record identical 
  patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency 
 for the D?il 
  ?ireann election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804 
  possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 
 25,101 unique 
  preference profiles.
 
 
  The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique 
  preference profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was 
  unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than 
  three preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of 
 candidates. I 
  understand the full preference profiles, probably at 
 precinct level, 
  will be published on the City website, but they are not there yet.
 
  James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Kathy Dopp
OK James. As I said before, I agree with you that you were giving the
total number of profiles *if* voters were allowed to rank all
candidates, which they were not allowed to do in Minneapolis or
elsewhere in the US public elections if I am right.

Further, I think that Robert is correct, that one could collapse the
last N profiles into prior profiles if that is the system that is used
(allowing ranking all candidates), although I do not think that gives
any advantage, practically, to the counting process and may even
complicate it.

My formula provides the more practical number of how many profiles are
allowed to be cast by voters and how many profiles are needed if one
wants to count the number of votes cast for each profile and make IRV
precinct-summable for an actual election.

Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make
precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of sums per
precinct as the number of candidates increases.

I think one thing that some election methods experts sometimes fail to
consider are the election administration practicalities that are
crucial to whether or not a method is functionally practical to
provide public oversight over.

I am fully aware that it is voting system technology, costs, and the
increasing impracticality of manually auditing the election if the
full range of preference profiles is allowed, if one is making an
attempt to use paper ballots, that limits the number of choices a
voter may fill out.  I've studied this issue for 7 years now.

Cheers,

Kathy

On Fri, Jan 22, 2010 at 4:08 AM, James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk wrote:
 Kathy
 I think my post made clear that I was referring only to preference 
 profiles.  I was not dealing with the situation where some
 artificial, and highly undesirable, restriction had been placed on the 
 numbers of rankings the voters could mark.

 I think my comments about the counting procedure adopted in Minneapolis 
 should have indicated that I am well aware of the
 restrictions that can be imposed.  But note that in Minneapolis the 
 restriction was an artificial one imposed by the certified
 counting machines available for use in the precincts.  There is nothing in 
 the Minneapolis Election Ordinance that imposes such a
 restriction.  So when Minneapolis can obtain certified counting machines that 
 can deal with fully ranked ballots, there will be no
 such restriction in practice.

 James

 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:43 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)


 James,

 Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters
 are allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an
 election contest. That may be true in Australia, but is not
 true in the US where typically voters are allowed to rank up
 to only three candidates.

 I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n
 candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV
 that I wrote a year or two ago:

 Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
 http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantR
 unoffVotingFlaws.pdf


 Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula,
 etc. here I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc
 linked above.

 Cheers,

 Kathy



  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
  I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the
  numbers of possible unique preference profiles for
 increasing numbers
  of candidates (N) as follows:
 
  N       Unique Preference Profiles
  2       4
  3       15
  4       64
  5       325
  6       1,956
  7       13,699
  8       109,600
  9       986,409
  10      9,864,100
  11      108,505,111
  12      1,302,061,344
  13      16,926,797,485
  14      236,975,164,804
  15      3,554,627,472,075
  16      56,874,039,553,216
  17      966,858,672,404,689
  18      17,403,456,103,284,400
  19      330,665,665,962,404,000
  20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000
 
 
  Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible
  number of unique preference profiles will be limited by the
 number of
  voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12
 candidates, the
  maximum possible number of preference profiles would be
 10,000 and not
  1,302,061,344.
 
  In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even
  lower, as significant numbers of voters would record identical
  patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency
 for the D?il
  ?ireann election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
  possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only
 25,101 unique
  preference profiles.
 
 
  The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique
  preference profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
  unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than
  three preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of
 candidates. I
  understand the full preference profiles, probably

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 1:42 PM
 
 OK James. As I said before, I agree with you that you were 
 giving the total number of profiles *if* voters were allowed 
 to rank all candidates, which they were not allowed to do in 
 Minneapolis or elsewhere in the US public elections if I am right.

In STV elections (STV, IRV, RCV) there should be NO restrictions of any kind on 
the number of rankings each voter may mark, up to
the limit of the number of candidates.  The voters should be completely free to 
mark as many or as few rankings as each wishes.


 Further, I think that Robert is correct, that one could 
 collapse the last N profiles into prior profiles if that is 
 the system that is used (allowing ranking all candidates), 
 although I do not think that gives any advantage, 
 practically, to the counting process and may even complicate it.

As I explained in my earlier post, whether or not you can do that depends on 
the version of the STV counting rules you have to use.


 My formula provides the more practical number of how many 
 profiles are allowed to be cast by voters and how many 
 profiles are needed if one wants to count the number of votes 
 cast for each profile and make IRV precinct-summable for an 
 actual election.

But if you do not report the complete preference profiles, down the last 
preference position (whether or not it is relevant to the
count), you reduce the transparency of the process.  The full ballot data 
should be published as soon as possible after the
election.  To provide complete information in the smallest size, the STV ballot 
data should be published as preference profiles,
i.e. COMPLETE preference profiles.  The BLT format is convenient for this.  The 
full ballot data from the 2007 STV-PR local
government elections in the City of Glasgow (Scotland) were published on the 
City Council's website as very soon after the count
closed on the day after polling.  They are still all there for inspection.


 Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make 
 precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of 
 sums per precinct as the number of candidates increases.

If you are going to do a manual sort of the ballots, then making three piles 
for each pair-wise comparison (AB, BA, neither
ranked) would involve less work than sorting to complete preference profiles.  
But if you have sensible processing equipment that
task is trivial and the difference irrelevant.


 I think one thing that some election methods experts 
 sometimes fail to consider are the election administration 
 practicalities that are crucial to whether or not a method is 
 functionally practical to provide public oversight over.

The practicalities of election administration are extremely important and as a 
returning officer for some elections, I am well aware
of that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put artificial or 
convenient limitations on the democratic process.


 I am fully aware that it is voting system technology, costs, 
 and the increasing impracticality of manually auditing the 
 election if the full range of preference profiles is allowed, 
 if one is making an attempt to use paper ballots, that limits 
 the number of choices a voter may fill out.  I've studied 
 this issue for 7 years now.

We have absolutely no problems with any of this in our STV public elections in 
the UK.  We always take all our paper ballots to one
counting centre for each electoral district.  In Northern Ireland, the ballots 
are sorted and counted manually, under scrutiny.  In
Scotland in 2007 we used optical scanning equipment and OCR to produce the vote 
vector for each ballot and the vote vectors were
then consolidated into preference profiles for the STV counting program.  All 
the ballot handling was done under scrutiny.  There
are always some who are unhappy with the results (defeated candidates and their 
supporters!), but the process has not been
challenged.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Fri, Jan 22, 2010 at 11:10 AM, James Gilmour
jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk wrote:
 Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 1:42 PM
 My formula provides the more practical number of how many
 profiles are allowed to be cast by voters and how many
 profiles are needed if one wants to count the number of votes
 cast for each profile and make IRV precinct-summable for an
 actual election.

 But if you do not report the complete preference profiles, down the last 
 preference position (whether or not it is relevant to the
 count), you reduce the transparency of the process.  The full ballot data 
 should be published as soon as possible after the
 election.  To provide complete information in the smallest size, the STV 
 ballot data should be published as preference profiles,
 i.e. COMPLETE preference profiles.  The BLT format is convenient for this.  
 The full ballot data from the 2007 STV-PR local
 government elections in the City of Glasgow (Scotland) were published on the 
 City Council's website as very soon after the count
 closed on the day after polling.  They are still all there for inspection.

James, you are using a straw man argument with me, setting up a false
premise that I said something I never did, rather than responding to
my formula which is more broad and general than yours. I.e. your
formula is a subset of mine where r, the number of candidates voters
may rank is equal to the number of candidates. Recall it was Robert
who suggested collapsing and not reporting all of the exact
preferences specified by voters, not myself, although I agree with
Robert that if the number of candidates equals the number of rankings
allowed, it could be collapsed for any IRV counting method I've heard
of, although you say that there are methods I've never heard of where
it could not be collapsed.

To require, as you suggest that all election be administered in a way
that allows all voters to fully rank all candidates may sounds nice
and would eliminate one of the problems with IRV, but with so many
election contests on one ballot here in the US, it would be costly and
possibly impractical unless you insist on using inauditable, easily
hacked, electronic ballots and touchscreen devices rather than
auditable voter marked paper ballots.

As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length of the
paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of candidates who can run
for office is unlimited and you want voters to be able to fully rank
(not that most voters would want to.)

Dealing with practical election administration issues seem to be very
low down on the totem pole for most electoral methods people it seems.



 Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make
 precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of
 sums per precinct as the number of candidates increases.

 If you are going to do a manual sort of the ballots, then making three piles 
 for each pair-wise comparison (AB, BA, neither
 ranked) would involve less work than sorting to complete preference profiles. 
  But if you have sensible processing equipment that
 task is trivial and the difference irrelevant.


Sorting ballots is not a logically coherent method of counting
Condorcet ballots James, so I'm not sure what you mean. Also, of
course three piles only works for the first round of sorting for an
IRV-type of count in the special case where there are three candidates
running for office, not for the general case of IRV and not for
Condorcet, so I have no idea what you're thinking about.

If you reread one of my recent emails, I describe the two methods for
handcounting IRV and the two methods for counting Condorcet.  The only
methods they have in common is to begin by sorting into all the unique
votes.  Sorting ballots into piles and confusing subpiles only works
for IRV and does not work for STV, except if there are no
transferrable votes or you want to cut up pieces of ballots or xerox
copies of ballots (what a confusing mess that would be.)




 I think one thing that some election methods experts
 sometimes fail to consider are the election administration
 practicalities that are crucial to whether or not a method is
 functionally practical to provide public oversight over.

 The practicalities of election administration are extremely important and as 
 a returning officer for some elections, I am well aware
 of that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put artificial 
 or convenient limitations on the democratic process.


Except in the case of such methods as IRV when the method is not only
wholly inconvenient and costly and virtually impossible to hand count
understandably and quickly and is also unfair and produces awful
outcomes.

A simpler method to administer is always preferable, other things
being equal, to a complex costly method such as IRV, but IRV does not
even provide any reason to use it since it fails more fairness
criteria than plurality, takes us backwards in election fairness 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Jonathan Lundell
On Jan 22, 2010, at 8:54 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

 As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length of the
 paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of candidates who can run
 for office is unlimited and you want voters to be able to fully rank
 (not that most voters would want to.)

What point are you making here? If the number of candidates is unlimited, then 
so is the length of the ballot, but that's true for any method that lists the 
candidates, including fptp and Condorcet methods.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:

This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes 
to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated 
differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable 
(exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.


You mean transferred to B, of course.

This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean 
it has not been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,

sadly, Scotland.


Not stupid, precisely because of the difference between AB and A. 
The former is an acceptance of the last listed preference, the latter 
is not. It makes a difference if a majority is required. Not if it is 
not, though it might make a difference with some methods. But not IRV.


 It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my vote 
could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible 
place, e.g. 12th out of 12 candidates.


Basically, if there are as many ranks as candidates, don't vote for 
that last one! That's your choice, unless full ranking is required, 
in which case you *can't* vote the truncated vote and it is 
irrelevant if it's counted or not.



  Following on from the
concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency 
voting, as in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances 
will her vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter 
end rule undermines this.


Only because of voter ignorance, an ignorance which has sometimes 
been encouraged by activists.


The ballot instructions should state that one should not rank any 
candidate one is not willing to support over alternatives. If there 
are twelve candidates on the ballot, and write-in votes are not 
allowed (is that the truth there)?, and a majority is not required, 
there should only be eleven ranks, not twelve. Otherwise the ballot 
encourages the behavior you don't like.


But with write-in votes allowed, you need twelve ranks to cover a 
single allowed write-in. So that's thirteen candidates. And then the 
ballot instruction is important, because otherwise voters will 
imagine they are voting maximally against a candidate with a ranking 
of 12th. Instead, in these conditions, it's a vote for a candidate as 
against any possible write-in, including one the voter might well 
have preferred if aware that a write-in candidate had a prayer.


You are right, there is a problem, but it isn't with the rule that 
continues to the end, it's with voter education. If a majority is not 
required, though, it's moot. But with better preferential voting 
methods than IRV, there is indeed a difference between AB and A.


I'm not at all convinced that full ranking provides useful 
information beyond the first few ranks. With Bucklin, three ranks are 
pretty obviously enough. In reality, in Bucklin elections, udner some 
conditions, only a bit over 10% of voters even used additional ranks.


It's not about later-no-harm, it's about how much information the 
voters have. If they have a strong preference for a frontrunner over 
all others, truncating is a perfectly sensible vote. It gets even 
more sensible if it's a runoff system.


If your voting method does indeed require a majority, why in the 
world do you add that 12th preference? By adding it, you are 
contributing to the community acceptance of the result, by 
withholding it, you are asking for a possible second chance for your favorite.


If a majority is required, the absolute Later No Harm promise of IRV 
is false. That's been missed by focus on the method as deterministic. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 4:54 PM
 James, you are using a straw man argument with me, setting up 
 a false premise that I said something I never did, 

Kathy, I was not setting up any straw man argument with you or anyone else.  I 
simply stated what a preference profile is and the
possible numbers of such profiles.  Anything else is not a preference profile 
and is irrelevant.

Of course, no-one in their right mind (or not under legal restraint) would do a 
manual count of STV ballots by sorting to preference
profiles.  It is completely unnecessary and would extend time taken for the 
count very greatly.  Sorting STV ballots to preference
profiles makes sense only in computerised counting.


 To require, as you suggest that all election be administered 
 in a way that allows all voters to fully rank all candidates 
 may sounds nice

No, Kathy it is not something that sounds nice  -  it is an essential 
requirement for the proper implementation of democratic
choice.  Any artificiality imposed constraint on that is a restriction of that 
democratic choice.  But I am aware that factors of
administrative convenience outweigh such considerations in some jurisdictions 
 -  it must be so, else they would never be
tolerated.


 and would eliminate one of the problems with 
 IRV, but with so many election contests on one ballot here in 
 the US, it would be costly and possibly impractical unless 
 you insist on using inauditable, easily hacked, electronic 
 ballots and touchscreen devices rather than auditable voter 
 marked paper ballots.

No, Kathy, here in the UK we do NOT use any easily hacked, electronic ballots 
and touchscreen devices.  We use good old-fashioned
paper ballots which we mark with a stubby pencil secured to the polling booth 
by a short length of string!  It is very old
technology, but it works, and it is extremely flexible in that this voting 
method (paper and pencil) can be adapted to any voting
system (and we use five different voting systems for public elections in 
Scotland).  And of course, where electronic counting is
employed, we always have the original paper ballots should anyone demand an 
audit.


 As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length 
 of the paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of 
 candidates who can run for office is unlimited and you want 
 voters to be able to fully rank (not that most voters would want to.)

Length has not been a problem.


 Dealing with practical election administration issues seem to 
 be very low down on the totem pole for most electoral methods 
 people it seems.

I cannot speak for any other EM member, but practical election administration 
is an important priority for me, especially as I am
the returning officer for some elections and the supervising officer for some 
others.


CUT

 Sorting ballots into 
 piles and confusing subpiles only works for IRV and does not 
 work for STV, except if there are no transferrable votes or 
 you want to cut up pieces of ballots or xerox copies of 
 ballots (what a confusing mess that would be.)

If by STV you mean STV-PR (a multi-seat election), this statement is 
nonsense.  IF you are sorting ballots into unique preference
profiles, that is as easily done for STV-PR as it is for IRV.  Of course, as I 
have already said, it makes no sense to do that in a
manual count of any IRV or STV-PR election.  And when it comes to the practical 
transfer of ballots in an STV-PR election there is
no problem at all, whether you are dealing with whole vote transfers on an 
exclusion or fractional transfers of a surplus.


  The practicalities of election administration are extremely important 
  and as a returning officer for some elections, I am well aware of 
  that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put 
  artificial or convenient limitations on the democratic process.
 
 
 Except in the case of such methods as IRV when the method is 
 not only wholly inconvenient and costly and virtually 
 impossible to hand count understandably and quickly and is 
 also unfair and produces awful outcomes.

IRV and STV-PR are quite easy to count by hand and the procedures and the 
outcomes are widely understood.  They have been doing just
that in Ireland and Malta since 1920, and in Northern Ireland again since 1973. 
 The multi-seat count may take longer than one
plurality count, but that one multi-seat count replaces several plurality 
counts.  And of course, there is no comparison at all in
what is achieved in terms of fair and democratic representation of the voters  
-  which should always be the deciding factor.



 A simpler method to administer is always preferable, other 
 things being equal, to a complex costly method such as IRV, 

But of course, other thing are not equal.  And there are higher priorities in 
achieving democratic representation than cost and
complexity.


 but IRV does not even provide any reason to use it since it 
 fails more fairness criteria 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 09:33 PM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:42 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.


James didn't put forth any formulae.  but he did put forth a table  ,
which appears to be consistent with

 N-1
P(N)  =  SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

he, appears to miss the same point as Abd and you do.


Okay, now, three missing Robert's point against Robert's superior 
opinion, as he insists, that totally ignores the substantial and 
thorough arguments and evidence presented and focuses on alleged 
errors in details.




That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.


where do you get your information, Kathy?  that is *not* at all the
case in the IRV election in Burlington VT.

or is Burlington untypical?


Yes, it is. Most IRV elections in the U.S. are Ranked Choice 
Voting, typically referring to a three-rank ballot, even if there 
are more than two candidates plus the write-in option.


Burlington allowed ranking of all candidates on the ballot. There 
were six slots and six candidates on the ballot. This allows full 
ranking, however, it is misleading a bit, because it encourages a 
voter to rank all the candidates, including the lowest preference, 
imagining that this last ranking is a vote against the candidate, 
when, in fact, it is a vote for the candidate under some conditions, 
a vote against every write-in, unless the voter explicitly ranks the 
write-in, which then *is* a vote against the unranked candidate.


Imagine that there is some write-in campaign that brings up a real 
possibility with, say, a three-rank ballot. With that 6-rank ballot, 
almost impossible for the candidate to win, because of the knee-jerk 
full ranking that some voters will do. If voters truncate, fine. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Abd ul-Rahman Lomax   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 5:53 PM
  At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:
 This
 second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes
 to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
 determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated 
 differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
 transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable 
 (exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.
 
 You mean transferred to B, of course.

Apologies - my example was incomplete.  To illustrate this stupid rule 
properly, I should have posited two candidates, A and B, (or
just two left after all others have been eliminated), with A the winner.  Then 
consider two ballots, one marked B and the other
marked BA.  In the last round of a count under the to the bitter end 
transfer rule, the ballot marked B would be
'non-transferrable (exhausted)', but the vote on the BA ballot would be 
transferred to A.  It is illogical to treat these ballots
differently in an STV (contingency choice) election and it offends the 
underlying concepts of 'Later No Harm' to transfer the BA
ballot to A.


 This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean
 it has not been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,
 sadly, Scotland.
 
 Not stupid, precisely because of the difference between AB and A. 
 The former is an acceptance of the last listed preference, the latter 
 is not. It makes a difference if a majority is required. Not if it is 
 not, though it might make a difference with some methods. But not IRV.

But my comments were exclusively in the context of STV elections (IRV, STV-PR, 
RCV).


   It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my vote
  could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
 the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible 
 place, e.g. 12th out of 12 candidates.
 
 Basically, if there are as many ranks as candidates, don't vote for 
 that last one! That's your choice, unless full ranking is required, 
 in which case you *can't* vote the truncated vote and it is 
 irrelevant if it's counted or not.

That's why when running an STV election where we can use write in boxes for 
all preferences, I always provide one fewer preference
box than the number of candidates (as I see you recommended in a later part of  
your post).  But all of our ballots for public
elections have the candidates names printed on them.


Following on from the
 concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency
 voting, as in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
 to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances 
 will her vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
 ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter 
 end rule undermines this.
 
 Only because of voter ignorance, an ignorance which has sometimes 
 been encouraged by activists.

No, not at all.  This is a piece of nonsense that some have introduced into STV 
counting, especially since electronic counting
became available.  It does not feature in any of the long-established versions 
of STV counting rules promoted in the UK.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 8:54 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 05:17 PM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

  and i believe that it is perfectly
practical when the number of *credible* candidates is small.  doesn't
matter what the voting system is.  IRV, or whatever.


Yes. But how small? Don't use the bogus numbers that aren't at all  
realistic given real-world election rules,


lotsa blather deleted and left unresponded

being 54 and having voted in every prez election since Carter-Ford  
(and aware of the 1968 election with Wallace-Nixon-Humphery), i have  
never once seen a presidential election in the US that had more than  
two candidates with any chance of winning, and no more than three  
candidates of national salience.


so my bogus number is 3, maybe 4 at the most.  individual precincts  
could total 40 different virtual piles.  doesn't matter what the  
counting method is, those precinct summable pile tallies are  
sufficient to completely describe the election for those 4.





  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to
be complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are
illegal and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally
equivalent to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are
collapsed and reported the same, to the displeasure of voting
security people who do want to know the error rate, which
includes overvoting and exact overvoting patterns. So-called ballot
images are not, generally. They are processed data reducing a
ballot to legally equivalent votes. The reduced set is this:

A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB

Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot.


no, it can be a 3-rank ballot where the voter declines to rate their
last choice.  3rd choice is left unmarked.


I meant something a little different. I address the possibility of  
a 3-rank ballot in the next section. The basic issue here is  
whether or not the third rank is irrelevant or not. If it's  
irrelevant, I claim, it's not really a three-rank ballot, it's got  
two relevant ranks and one that means nothing. Why was it even there?




blather.  you said absolutely nothing of substance.


It also assumes that majority vote isn't important.


bullshit.  it (the number of consequential ballot permutations) has
nothing to do with it (whether or not majority vote is important).


This is, in fact, serious ignorance. Bullshit, properly used,  
allows things to grow. Consider where the growth lies here.


If a majority is required, there is a difference in meaning between  
BCA and BC. I will assume the counting method described by  
Robert's Rules of Order for preferential voting. 3 candidates


Situation with truncated B vote:
35 AB
34 BC
31 C

C eliminated, votes become

35 AB
34 B

Majority basis is 100. 51 votes are required to win. No majority, B  
eliminated. I would guess that Robert doesn't consider this step  
because he is used to thinking of plurality IRV, no majority  
required, and the counting can stop with the last two in that case.  
A would win.


35 AB. A is plurality winner, no majority, election fails. Who  
would be the runoff candidates? Under Robert's Rules, the question  
is unanswerable and undeterminable from the first round results.  
It's a new election. Under top two runoff rules, the rules were not  
designed for a preferential ballot, but I'd suggest considering  
*every IRV vote* as an approval, then pick the top two in that.


so you're making up rules to prove a point.  chapter 13, section 45  
of RONR (regarding preferential voting) have *no* consequential  
difference between marking the last preference last or deducing the  
same preference is last because it is the *only* one remaining unmarked.


there is no consequential difference between.

  35  AB
  34  BC
  31  C

and

  35  AB
  34  BCA
  31  C

or

  35  ABC
  34  BCA
  31  C

end of discussion.



 Pay attention, Robert, there is far more here than you imagine.


the problem for you is that i *am* paying attention.  you're wrong  
and, by examination, that fact that you're wrong becomes manifest.


the rest of the blather is deleted without comment.

people need to warned that, although you fancy yourself an expert,  
you are not.  you make things up.  they should just ignore you.



--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 22, 2010, at 3:57 AM, James Gilmour wrote:


robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:25 AM

On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:


N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15

...

then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you

ostensibly need

4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.



If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique
preference profiles are:
A   
B   
AB  
BA




what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between
A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one
marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses
ranked ballots?


In terms of preference profiles the question is completely  
irrelevant.  A and AB are two different preference profiles.  So
the possible numbers of preference profiles for given numbers of  
candidates are, I think, correctly stated in the table in my

earlier post.

How the STV counting rules handle the two preference profiles A  
and AB is a different matter.  Some STV counting rules handle
these two profiles identically.  But for some other STV counting  
rules the profiles A and AB are handled differently.  This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes  
to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been

determined.


so what consequential difference is that?

  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated differently  
from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable  
(exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.


now remember in the case we're discussing here, there is only two  
candidates.  again, what consequence to the outcome of the election  
(that is, who of A or B wins) occurs whether a ballot is marked  
A (and B is last by default) or is marked AB?


there is none.

i'm not going to discuss this any more with Abd, because he's not a  
straight shooter, but James, if you want to get into this, it's  
pretty much cut and dried from the POV of Information Theory (a.la.  
Claude Shannon).  it's a discipline within my purview (being an  
electrical engineer that does signal processing), but the fundamental  
fact comes early.  for information to be transmitted from one  
location (the voter and his ballot) to another location (the ballot  
counters), it is necessary that such information does not exist at  
the destination prior.  Information Theory is about the measure of  
how much information is contained in a message and how many bits one  
bests commit to a message.


the first three statements following provide a non-zero amount of  
information (providing the destination was originally ignorant of the  
same).  the fourth statement (given the first three) has a measure of  
information of precisely zero (which means that it is inconsequential  
whether the message is transmitted or not).


1.  there are three eligible candidates, A, B, and C.
2.  a particular voter has A as his/her first preference.
3.  the same voter has B as the second preference.
4.  the same voter has C as the last preference.

when i taught Information Theory (just once, almost two decades ago),  
i was sorta enamored of some of George Carlin's humor and found an  
interesting example i used to illustrate a similar point.  Consider a  
weather forecast (say on TV).  If it were to say tonight's forecast:  
snow, that would have some real information and the number of bits  
needed to encode it is greater than zero.  But now consider Carlin's  
Hippie-Dippie Weatherman, Al Sleet: Tonight's forecast: Dark.  
Continued dark throughout most of the evening, with some widely- 
scattered light towards morning. If you're not considering Joshua in  
the Old Testament, how much information is in that forecast?


in general, the number of bits inherent to a particular message,  
given the probability of occurrence of the message, is:


I(m) = -log2( p(m) )(base 2 log and p(m) is the probability)

if p(m)=1, there is no information content in the message.   
committing bits or words or time to saying it is redundant.



again, the number of piles *necessary* (for recording and  
transmitting the information) when there are precisely N distinct  
candidates is


   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=1

not

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=0

the latter redundantly (and unnecessarily) divides N! piles into  
twice that number with no difference of information between the two  
piles of each pair.



this is not social science.  it's not politics.  it's not opinion.   
it's just math.


i think i am now going to bow out of this.

it's similar to the alien abduction controversy.  no matter how many  
people claim to be abducted by extra-terrestials and can provide  
vivid and detailed information of they're alleged abduction (and even  
scars, where they stuck the needles in), 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 01:55 PM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:

Abd ul-Rahman Lomax   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 5:53 PM
  At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:
 This
 second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes
 to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
 determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated
 differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
 transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable
 (exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.

 You mean transferred to B, of course.

Apologies - my example was incomplete.  To illustrate this stupid 
rule properly, I should have posited two candidates, A and B, (or
just two left after all others have been eliminated), with A the 
winner.  Then consider two ballots, one marked B and the other
marked BA.  In the last round of a count under the to the bitter 
end transfer rule, the ballot marked B would be
'non-transferrable (exhausted)', but the vote on the BA ballot 
would be transferred to A.  It is illogical to treat these ballots
differently in an STV (contingency choice) election and it offends 
the underlying concepts of 'Later No Harm' to transfer the BA

ballot to A.


If truncation is allowed, there is a difference, as you know. 
However, if a plurality of ballots is sufficient for victory, it's 
irrelevant to the result. The real difference shows up when a true 
majority is required.


In Australia, they use the term absolute majority as the quota that 
must be reached, but that is with mandatory full ranking. So there is 
never majority failure, absent a tie, and a majority is always found 
when there are only two candidates still standing. Where truncation 
is permitted, which is in a few places in Australia, they change the 
quota to a majority of votes for candidates not eliminated. That, 
too, never requires that last counting step.


But we have been discussing the general case, and that case most 
notably includes elections as described in Robert's Rules of Order, 
Newly Revised, RRONR 10th edition, where a single-transferable vote 
method is described for single-winner (and a multiwinner variation is 
also described, a detail I won't address). RRONR never permits 
election without a majority unless a special bylaw has been passed 
allowing election by plurality. Which is strongly discouraged.


FairVote managed to confuse nearly everyone with their description of 
what is in Robert's Rules. They have slightly modified their rhetoric 
since I started nailing them on this, so that generally they aren't 
actually lying any more, but they still cherry-pick and create 
deceptive implications. If a majority is sought, and full ranking is 
optional, and the ballots are ones on which the voter writes 
candidates in order of preference, going to the last elimination is 
quite proper, for one has thereby found all the ballots containing a 
vote for the leader. If that is not a majority of all ballots, the 
election fails.


And, yes, this violates Later No Harm. If only a plurality is 
required, Later No Harm is not violated. LNH is incompatible with a 
majority requirement, unless voters are coerced or misled, that is 
one of the dirty little secrets of IRV.


In RRONR elections, the voters are not constrained to a list of 
candidates. In the normal procedure, the ballots are blank, and the 
voter writes down the names of candidates, ranking them. The voter 
may vote for *anyone*, including ineligible candidates or Donald 
Duck, or, more importantly, Mr. None of the Above.


Why does RRONR even propose the STV method? Good question! They 
propose it in cases where repeated balloting is not considered 
practical. But they think of it as a way to find a majority, and they 
advise the voters to rank all the candidates, cautioning that if 
they don't, it is possible that no candidate will get a majority, 
thus requiring the election to be repeated.


Now, this is what I've found in studying U.S. elections with IRV. In 
partisan elections, IRV sometimes works and finds a better winner, 
clearly more democratic, than FPTP or Plurality. In nonpartisan 
elections, however, at least in these public elections studied, IRV 
simply reproduces the results of Plurality. There is enough evidence 
to come to the conclusion that exceptions would be rare and typically 
close elections.


We have been discussing the election in Burlington, Vermont. There, a 
naive impression can be created that Plurality would have elected 
Wright, the Republican, he did get the most first preference votes. 
However, prior to IRV being adopted there, they used top two runoff, 
with a 40% requirement for election, otherwise a runoff was held 
between the top two. The runoff would have been between Kiss and 
Wright. Likely result would have been the same as with IRV.


The problem is that, while Kiss was a better winner than Wright, the 
eliminated Democrat, Montroll, was a beats-all winner, based on the 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
WARNING: this is a metacommunication, about the communication process 
here and elsewhere in voting system advocacy, not about voting methods, per se.


At 01:48 AM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 20, 2010, at 11:23 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.


you do?  you keep saying that you can see it.


Yes, I said that. Slip is showing is a metaphor, stating that 
something relatively unmentionable is visible. I can see something. 
Others can see something. Do you see or know what we see? Perhaps you 
do, but you are defending yourself as if you cannot see it. Others 
who do see it might respond differently.


This is meta talk, it's about the communication, not election 
methods. I will therefore limit it to what's relevant to the 
*extended* purposes of this list, which include voting system 
advocacy, not merely theory.


If you are going to be a public advocate, you will be much more 
effective if you know how your actions and words will be seen, and if 
you can learn as much as possible about debate tactics and strategy.



Silly hat, Off.

Robert, if you want to be effective in public debate,


what makes you think i'm not effective?  do you actually think you
were effective?


1. I suspect you are less effective than you can be. You get caught, 
easily, in irrelevancies, distracting from the central points to be 
conveyed. As a public activist, to be effective, you must use polemic 
and all the skills of advocacy, which is different from discussion. 
Here, we discuss, and no collective decisions are actually made here. 
However, I inferred from behavior here what might happen in a public 
debate. If, in fact, some of this behavior carries over to public 
debate, you could get creamed. Unnecessarily. That is, over your own 
style and personality, not over the issue you are advocating.


2. Was I effective? In what? I'm engaged only in a diffuse kind of 
advocacy here. However, I've also repeated ideas that I've expressed 
here many times, and this is part of my own learning and polishing 
process. This is of benefit to those who find it useful to follow my 
discussions, to explore these topics repeatedly so that they become 
familiar, and so that deeper understanding spreads. It's my method 
and approach, and it certainly is not for everyone. Were I to do in a 
public forum, not a specialized forum like this, what I do here, I'd 
almost completely fail.


(3.) I have, however, come to the point that I'm sufficiently 
familiar with the issues that I'd engage, if invited, in public 
debate. I'm an effective speaker, making clear and direct contact 
with the audience. We'll see if that happens. I have made blog posts 
in public fora on these issues, they are far briefer, in general. The 
effort per word and per message is much higher for them.



i won't slap on the argumentum verbosium and explode the debate
about a single testable issue (like how many piles one needs if there
are 3 candidates) into pages and pages, that when i responded, my
post was rejected by the list server as too large.


Oh, we are crushed at the loss actually, usually it isn't exactly 
rejected, it is held for moderator approval, which can take some time. Depends.



I'd suggest avoiding setting up an immediate victory by the other
side by feeding him or her lines like that.


you're the one feeding lines.


Sure. Like a debate opponent might. Your slip is showing is a 
metacommunication to the audience, calling attention very briefly to 
the opponent's behavior, or sometimes to an issue of substance 
(possibly). As an ad hominem argument, it's irrelevant, but in real 
debate, it could be very important. People respond to the person, 
usually, more than to the substance. They judge the substance by the 
person. Only in careful deliberative process is this effect reduced much.



  who brought up the slip showing in
the first place?


Me. A stand-in for your debate opponent. However, it wasn't intended 
as a debate tactic, but as personal advice, which you could take or 
leave. You took it, in fact, but as if it were bait in a debate, and 
you also took, therefore, the hook and the line. And in so doing, you 
got jerked out of the water. My judgement. Yours might be different, 
but if you really want to know, ask someone neutral.



  how does one respond when facing: Your slip is
showing, now onto a verbose response that does not speak to the core
factual issues at all.


How? It's actually terminally easy. No response at all is probably 
the most efficient. A quick joke, though, may be even more efficient. 
Learn to think on your feet, if you have to puzzle over this, no 
response is better. Robert, your slip is showing was very efficient 
for me, it took, 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 3:24 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

WARNING: this is a metacommunication, about the communication  
process here and elsewhere in voting system advocacy, not about  
voting methods, per se.


At 01:48 AM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 20, 2010, at 11:23 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.


you do?  you keep saying that you can see it.


Yes, I said that. Slip is showing is a metaphor, stating that  
something relatively unmentionable is visible. I can see something.  
Others can see something. Do you see or know what we see? Perhaps  
you do, but you are defending yourself as if you cannot see it.  
Others who do see it might respond differently.


better say what it is right now, or you're just blowing smoke (to  
make use of another metaphor).


1. I suspect you are less effective than you can be. You get  
caught, easily, in irrelevancies, distracting from the central  
points to be conveyed.


it wasn't me that amplified the length of text by a factor of 10.  i  
was trying to keep it focused and my mistake was responding to your  
asides.


As a public activist, to be effective, you must use polemic and all  
the skills of advocacy, which is different from discussion. Here,  
we discuss, and no collective decisions are actually made here.  
However, I inferred from behavior here what might happen in a  
public debate. If, in fact, some of this behavior carries over to  
public debate, you could get creamed. Unnecessarily. That is, over  
your own style and personality, not over the issue you are advocating.


blather.

(quoting Warren Smith.)

2. Was I effective? In what? I'm engaged only in a diffuse kind of  
advocacy here. However, I've also repeated ideas that I've  
expressed here many times, and this is part of my own learning and  
polishing process. This is of benefit to those who find it useful  
to follow my discussions, to explore these topics repeatedly so  
that they become familiar, and so that deeper understanding  
spreads. It's my method and approach, and it certainly is not for  
everyone. Were I to do in a public forum, not a specialized forum  
like this, what I do here, I'd almost completely fail.


more blather.

(3.) I have, however, come to the point that I'm sufficiently  
familiar with the issues that I'd engage, if invited, in public  
debate. I'm an effective speaker, making clear and direct contact  
with the audience. We'll see if that happens. I have made blog  
posts in public fora on these issues, they are far briefer, in  
general. The effort per word and per message is much higher for them.


sometimes effective public speakers are successful not because of  
their efforts to focus the issue, but because of their efforts to  
distract.  e.g. Sarah Palin.



i won't slap on the argumentum verbosium and explode the debate
about a single testable issue (like how many piles one needs if there
are 3 candidates) into pages and pages, that when i responded, my
post was rejected by the list server as too large.


Oh, we are crushed at the loss actually, usually it isn't  
exactly rejected, it is held for moderator approval, which can take  
some time. Depends.


i'm not messing with it further.  i just ask that you don't amplify  
the quantity of responses by a factor of 10 and bring your post to  
40K so that if anyone actually bothers to read through it and respond  
to most or all of the points, their effort goes into the trash can.   
since your name was in the To: header, you got that response, but no  
one else did.


what i have learned from that is to not play your argumentum  
verbosium game.  from now on, i must pick and choose, respond to  
only one point, delete all the other blather, and keep the issue  
focussed.


thus i am deleting and not bothering to engage in the other text.

care to discuss how many piles one needs (for precinct summability)  
when there are N candidates?  or N credible candidates?  that's what  
the issue was before it was buried in blather.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Jameson Quinn
People, please. This is not a debate class, and even if it were, no, I won
is really useless even if true. Please take this discussion off list, if you
find it important enough not to stop. There's practically no voting system
content left. As for what is left: we all know that the number of piles is
large, that full ballots can be transmitted, and we can work out the
implications to our own perhaps-incorrect satisfaction.

Respectfully to you both, but tired of this wordy debate,
Jameson

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


i just want to settle the issue about how many piles one needs to be  
precinct summable when there are N candidates.


Kathy was pointing to Abd ul as the qualified actor who refuted the  
falsifiable assertion that i made that you needed only 9 piles for 3  
candidates.  She repeated labeled (without any justification other  
than citing Abd ul's blather) the math that i clearly presented as  
illogical.  Abd ul did nothing to support Kathy's assertion.


Kathy, fancying herself as an election security expert, continues to  
try to taint IRV as being insecure because it's not precinct  
summable.  and that is a demonstrably false claim.


i'll leave it to the experts here to judge who was trying to stay on  
topic and who was decreasing the signal-to-noise ratio with  
unnecessary text (with aim to distract from the core issue and to  
denigrate the other side).


r b-j

On Jan 21, 2010, at 3:56 PM, Jameson Quinn wrote:

People, please. This is not a debate class, and even if it were,  
no, I won is really useless even if true. Please take this  
discussion off list, if you find it important enough not to stop.  
There's practically no voting system content left. As for what is  
left: we all know that the number of piles is large, that full  
ballots can be transmitted, and we can work out the implications to  
our own perhaps-incorrect satisfaction.


Respectfully to you both, but tired of this wordy debate,
Jameson


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 01:48 AM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

the fact is, transmitting the content (to a central counting
location) of *every ballot* is the transfer of a finite amount of
information.  that is even *more* general than sorting to piles and
transmitting the tallies for piles.


Yes, of course. And this is an equivalent to carrying all the ballots 
to a central location, merely, if done, say, over the internet, faster.


But ... it raises some security issues. And with central counting 
there are other issues. This is a red herring, because we are talking 
about precinct summability, and when the number of candidates is very 
small, precinct summability isn't relevant, because the raw ballot 
data may be transmitted.


So, back to the real question: is precinct summability an important 
practical criterion to be applied to voting systems? A related 
question is the sensitivity of the method to small variations in 
votes. Noise, if you will. That can be seen with Yee diagrams, in the 
presence of chaotic regions in issue space, with IRV. But I won't 
address that here, beyond noting that IRV multiples the probability 
of ties, and many of the ties will drastically flip the overall 
result. With most other methods, there is only one relevant tie 
possible (beyond extraordinarily rare three-way ties) and when this 
happens, a coin flip doesn't change the expected voter satisfaction 
much, if at all. With IRV, the effect can be enormous, because the 
tie can affect a candidate elimination before all the votes for that 
candidate have been counted.



but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation
of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite
number of piles.


Sure. Finite. I'll point out that a google is finite. With 
computers, this can be done even with moderately large numbers of 
candidates. It's still a problem with voting security, though. I've 
argued for Public Ballot Imaging, which would make available actual 
ballot images, transmitted from polling places, perhaps by fax or 
more likely through digital camera images -- no touching of ballots 
necessary except by election officers, all visible openly --, 
independently by voting watchdog organization through election 
observers, so that anyone can verify the count in a precinct or as 
many as they care, or can even just check one serialized ballot 
(serialized before counting) and mark it as reviewed, in a system 
that collects and displays such reviews. Many details omitted here!



  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to be 
complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are illegal 
and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally equivalent 
to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are collapsed and 
reported the same, to the displeasure of voting security people who 
do want to know the error rate, which includes overvoting and exact 
overvoting patterns. So-called ballot images are not, generally. They 
are processed data reducing a ballot to legally equivalent votes. The 
reduced set is this:


A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB

Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot. It also assumes that majority 
vote isn't important. If it's important, as it would be in an IRV 
election under Robert's Rules, we have some more possibilities. They 
are all the three-rank permutations.


ABC
ACB
BAC
BCA
CAB
CBA

Each of these is equivalent, for the purposes of finding a plurality 
winner, to a two-candidate combination.



  if you or
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's
showing).


Well, I won't speak about Kathy, but in terms of practical elections 
in the U.S., she's right. You did not state enough information to 
establish your reduced count, and you actually added language that 
indicated that a larger total would be necessary. You used the 
qualifier credible to indicate that there might be candidates not 
credible, and you did not take care to define this. What you have 
asserted is true under two qualifications: there are only three 
candidates legally eligible to receive votes. And there are only two 
ranks on the ballot. If there are three ranks on the ballot, we have 
a poor situation, an invitation to voters to cast an irrelevant vote, 
if, in fact, that third rank has any effect on outcome, which, in the 
general case, it can. If it can affect outcome in some way, the piles 
must be reported separately.



  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 40.


Under the restricted conditions, perhaps. I haven't checked the math. 
I distrust formulas compared to exhaustive enumeration, they take 
more work and there is more room for error. My lists, which I 
provided before, showed what is shown above, though it may be better 
explained this time.


The slip is an assumption that one's analysis is more complete than 
that of another, when it may be, instead, ignorant of some of the 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson

On Jan 21, 2010, at 4:26 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

But ... it raises some security issues. And with central counting  
there are other issues. This is a red herring, because we are  
talking about precinct summability, and when the number of  
candidates is very small, precinct summability isn't relevant,  
because the raw ballot data may be transmitted.


no, the problem is that the raw ballot data may be the only practical  
information to transmitt if the number of candidates is *large*, not  
very small.  when the number of candidates is very small, then it  
makes sense to transmit the tallies for piles because the number of  
piles, which are precinct summable, is manageable.


So, back to the real question: is precinct summability an important  
practical criterion to be applied to voting systems?


i would ask instead if precinct summability is important for  
security?  i believe that it is.  and i believe that it is perfectly  
practical when the number of *credible* candidates is small.  doesn't  
matter what the voting system is.  IRV, or whatever.



  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to  
be complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are  
illegal and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally  
equivalent to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are  
collapsed and reported the same, to the displeasure of voting  
security people who do want to know the error rate, which  
includes overvoting and exact overvoting patterns. So-called ballot  
images are not, generally. They are processed data reducing a  
ballot to legally equivalent votes. The reduced set is this:


A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB

Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot.


no, it can be a 3-rank ballot where the voter declines to rate their  
last choice.  3rd choice is left unmarked.



It also assumes that majority vote isn't important.


bullshit.  it (the number of consequential ballot permutations) has  
nothing to do with it (whether or not majority vote is important).


If it's important, as it would be in an IRV election under Robert's  
Rules, we have some more possibilities. They are all the three-rank  
permutations.


ABC
ACB
BAC
BCA
CAB
CBA

Each of these is equivalent, for the purposes of finding a  
plurality winner, to a two-candidate combination.


it's equivalent for the purposes of IRV or Condorcet or *any* method  
that relies solely on the relative rank of candidates.  those 6  
markings are equivalent to the corresponding 6 above.





  if you or
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's
showing).


Well, I won't speak about Kathy, but in terms of practical  
elections in the U.S., she's right. You did not state enough  
information to establish your reduced count, ...


yes i did state enough information.  may i remind you?  i said that  
there is *no* consequential difference in these two marked ballots  
(in the case of N=3).  there is no consequential difference between a  
ballot marked AB to one marked ABC .  there is no election  
scenario, whether it's IRV, Condorcet, Borda or any other method  
using ranked ballots that will count those two ballots differently.   
there is no need to separate the AB and ABC into two piles.



  for N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=1

not

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=0

which is appears to be the formula you and Kathy continue to insist
is correct.


Which it is under some conditions and yours is correct under some  
conditions. I assume. I haven't checked them because it's more work  
than I can put in now.


want me to spell it out.  it's a simple application of combinatorial  
analysis, what is the first chapter of my introductory probability  
textbook (of a course i took more than 3 decades ago).  you're doing  
it already for the specific case of 3 candidates A, B, and C.  if you  
want to look it up, look for language that says something like: how  
many unique ways can a group of n items be selected from a pool of N  
items when the order of selection is relevant?  and the answer to  
that is N!/n! .  but there is one more fact that you need to toss  
in.  and that fact is that all candidates unmarked or unranked are  
tied for last place.  if there is only one candidate left unmarked,  
we know how all N candidates are ranked, including the unmarked  
candidate.


everything else between is deleted without comment

A vote of ABC, is that the same as AB? Robert assumes, yes. But  
what about write-ins? ABC is equivalent to ABCW.


that's not 3 candidates.  that's four.  you just changed the  
premise.  that's an official logical fallacy.  a form of straw man.


if the write-ins are insignificant (usually the case) we can sweep  
them all into a single insignificant candidate and we have 4  
candidates and 40 piles.  but we'll see that 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, January 21, 2010 6:49 AM
 but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation  
 of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite  
 number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or  
 Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's  
 showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 
 40.
  for  N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is
 
 N-1
  P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=1
 
 not
 
 N-1
  P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the numbers of 
possible unique preference profiles for increasing
numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15
4   64
5   325
6   1,956
7   13,699
8   109,600
9   986,409
10  9,864,100
11  108,505,111
12  1,302,061,344
13  16,926,797,485
14  236,975,164,804
15  3,554,627,472,075
16  56,874,039,553,216
17  966,858,672,404,689
18  17,403,456,103,284,400
19  330,665,665,962,404,000
20  6,613,313,319,248,080,000


Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible number of 
unique preference profiles will be limited by the number
of voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 candidates, the maximum 
possible number of preference profiles would be
10,000 and not 1,302,061,344.

In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even lower, as 
significant numbers of voters would record identical
patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency for the Dáil Éireann 
election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 25,101 unique 
preference profiles.


The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique preference 
profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than three 
preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of candidates.
I understand the full preference profiles, probably at precinct level, will be 
published on the City website, but they are not there
yet.

James Gilmour



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2636 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
07:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 6:30 PM, James Gilmour wrote:


robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, January 21, 2010 6:49 AM

but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation
of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite
number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's
showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is
40.
 for  N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is

N-1
 P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
n=1

not

N-1
 P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
n=0


I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the  
numbers of possible unique preference profiles for increasing

numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15

...

then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need  
4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread James Gilmour
  N   Unique Preference Profiles
  2   4
  3   15
 ...
 
 then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need  
 4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.
 

If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique preference 
profiles are: 
A   
B   
A  B
B  A

Anything that does not conform to this is an incorrect use of the term 
preference profile.

James Gilmour




No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2636 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
07:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:


N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15

...

then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need
4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.



If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique  
preference profiles are:	

A   
B   
AB  
BA




what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between  
A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one  
marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses  
ranked ballots?


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Kathy Dopp
 ballot to legally equivalent votes. The reduced set is this:

 A
 B
 C
 AB
 AC
 BA
 BC
 CA
 CB

 Note that this assumes a 2-rank ballot.

 no, it can be a 3-rank ballot where the voter declines to rate their
 last choice.  3rd choice is left unmarked.

 It also assumes that majority vote isn't important.

 bullshit.  it (the number of consequential ballot permutations) has
 nothing to do with it (whether or not majority vote is important).

 If it's important, as it would be in an IRV election under Robert's
 Rules, we have some more possibilities. They are all the three-rank
 permutations.

 ABC
 ACB
 BAC
 BCA
 CAB
 CBA


 Well, I won't speak about Kathy, but in terms of practical
 elections in the U.S., she's right. You did not state enough
 information to establish your reduced count, ...

 yes i did state enough information.  may i remind you?  i said that
 there is *no* consequential difference in these two marked ballots
 (in the case of N=3).  there is no consequential difference between a
 ballot marked AB to one marked ABC .  there is no election
 scenario, whether it's IRV, Condorcet, Borda or any other method
 using ranked ballots that will count those two ballots differently.
 there is no need to separate the AB and ABC into two piles.

OK. I understand now why you are confused Robert:

 1. on the formula for the number of possible unique candidate
orderings for any rank choice voting method  you incorrectly assume
that the number of possible ballot rankings that a voter may fill out
is always equal to the number of candidates running for office and so
you can collapse N of the rankings, but this simply is not the case
in US IRV elections and it would just be unnecessarily confusing to
collapse rankings for the special (and unusual) case when there are
three candidates and three rankings, when a more general formula that
always applies to all situations regardless of the number of
candidates and allowed rankings could be used; and

2. on the fact that IRV and Condorcet must be reported similarly and
counted similarly, because there are different methods available to
count each one.

With Condorcet, you can easily count it with an NxN matrix and you
cannot count IRV that way at all generally (although I wouldn't put it
past you to find an unusual special case where you could).

With IRV, you can count it (albeit not easily depending on the number
of candidates) with sorting into piles, but you cannot count Condorcet
method that way.

You can count either Condorcet or IRV by sorting into unique vote
orderings, as I gave you the general formula for that works in all
cases earlier. However that would be a very difficult and
time-consuming way to count Condorcet since Condorcet is
precinct-summable in the far simpler n x n matrix.  It is the only way
to make IRV precinct summable using the formulas I gave you earlier or
you can look them up in my IRV report, unless you want to publicly
report all voters' individual choices. Minneapolis chose to use the
first method.

I.e. The counting methods available and ideally used for Condorcet and
IRV are different.

-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Kathy Dopp
James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.
That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.

I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n
candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV that I wrote
a year or two ago:

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf


Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula, etc. here
I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc linked above.

Cheers,

Kathy



 From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
 I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the numbers of 
 possible unique preference profiles for increasing
 numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

 N       Unique Preference Profiles
 2       4
 3       15
 4       64
 5       325
 6       1,956
 7       13,699
 8       109,600
 9       986,409
 10      9,864,100
 11      108,505,111
 12      1,302,061,344
 13      16,926,797,485
 14      236,975,164,804
 15      3,554,627,472,075
 16      56,874,039,553,216
 17      966,858,672,404,689
 18      17,403,456,103,284,400
 19      330,665,665,962,404,000
 20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000


 Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible number of 
 unique preference profiles will be limited by the number
 of voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 candidates, the 
 maximum possible number of preference profiles would be
 10,000 and not 1,302,061,344.

 In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even lower, as 
 significant numbers of voters would record identical
 patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency for the D?il ?ireann 
 election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
 possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 25,101 unique 
 preference profiles.


 The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique preference 
 profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
 unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than three 
 preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of candidates.
 I understand the full preference profiles, probably at precinct level, will 
 be published on the City website, but they are not there
 yet.

 James Gilmour


-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:42 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


James,

Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters are
allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an election contest.


James didn't put forth any formulae.  but he did put forth a table  
which appears to be consistent with


 N-1
P(N)  =  SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

he, appears to miss the same point as Abd and you do.


That may be true in Australia, but is not true in the US where
typically voters are allowed to rank up to only three candidates.


where do you get your information, Kathy?  that is *not* at all the  
case in the IRV election in Burlington VT.


or is Burlington untypical?

--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 05:17 PM 1/21/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 21, 2010, at 4:26 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


But ... it raises some security issues. And with central counting
there are other issues. This is a red herring, because we are
talking about precinct summability, and when the number of
candidates is very small, precinct summability isn't relevant,
because the raw ballot data may be transmitted.


no, the problem is that the raw ballot data may be the only practical
information to transmitt if the number of candidates is *large*, not
very small.  when the number of candidates is very small, then it
makes sense to transmit the tallies for piles because the number of
piles, which are precinct summable, is manageable.


This is correct. I actually stated it oppositely, slip of the pen, so 
to speak. It's still a red herring, because the topic is precinct 
summability and the general use of precinct sums. The only precinct 
sum that can be used with IRV is the relevant-ballot-pattern summary, 
which becomes extremely large very rapidly. Forget about it with 
manual ballots and more than a quite small number of candidates. 
Remember, as well, that preferential voting, like top-two runoff, 
encourages lots of candidates to run, since they can do so with 
relative safety and get a payoff: some first rank votes that show 
support. They can turn that into cash in the next election when they 
are seeking the office again, or in other ways.



So, back to the real question: is precinct summability an important
practical criterion to be applied to voting systems?


i would ask instead if precinct summability is important for
security?  i believe that it is.


Good. So do I. Or was that a slip?


  and i believe that it is perfectly
practical when the number of *credible* candidates is small.  doesn't
matter what the voting system is.  IRV, or whatever.


Yes. But how small? Don't use the bogus numbers that aren't at all 
realistic given real-world election rules, and since we are talking 
about the U.S., there must be accomodation for every ballot candidate 
that gets any votes at all in the precinct, plus a write-in provision 
at a minimum, and God help the election officials if there are a 
*lot* of write-in candidates, with the sum being more than enough to 
alter the elimination sequence for the remaining candidate. 
Write-ins, in all the actual election reported counts, are counted as 
a category and then dropped when the total for all of them was 
insufficient to do other then batch-eliminate them, possibly with 
other candidates as I've seen. I.e., one assumes the simplest case, 
that all the write-in votes are for the same candidate.


Now, if it turns out that the write-ins are relevant, suppose that we 
set up some rule to lump all candidates with only one vote and report 
all the others explicitly. But the problem rapidly gets hairy. One 
has to report another candidate as relevant in addition to all the write-ins.


For voting system security issues, one must be able to count the 
votes manually, as part of an audit. I'm sure that Kathy could 
explain audit process, but, again, it gets very hairy rapidly with 
IRV, because vote samples aren't enough, given the sensitivity of the 
method to many small differences in vote patterns. What is actually 
being done? Only ballot images, with machines that collect and report 
them, in toto, from the precinct. In other words, the only solution 
in actual usage that doesn't involve toting all the ballots to a 
central location involves reporting ballot images. But this is 
precisely a system that is quite vulnerable to hacking and some very 
real voting security issues. If there are no paper ballots or at 
least bulletproof paper records that the voter personally verified, 
it's impossible to verify that there were no shenanigans. Precinct 
summable methods are not nearly as sensitive to manipulation as are 
IRV totals, it appears. It can only take a very small shift in voting 
patterns to shift an IRV result, under some conditions, and this 
isn't merely a very close election in terms of overall support for a 
candidate, it gets down to exact preference order and how it 
interacts with elimination sequence, which is determined sometimes at 
many places in the election process. And, note: if it's ballot 
images, these images don't include, generally, the actual write-in 
votes. If it turns out that write-ins need to be counted, only manual 
counting can do it, the name was hand written on a record, if I'm correct.




  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.


Okay, three candidates, A, B, C, the ballot possibilities are, to
be complete, much more than 9. I'll assume that write-ins are
illegal and void the ballot. Some of the possibilities are legally
equivalent to others, and in actual IRV ballot imaging, they are
collapsed and reported the same, to the displeasure of voting
security people who do want to know the error rate, which
includes overvoting and 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:01 AM 1/17/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 17, 2010, at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range
requires too much information from the voter.


well, it does force the voter to consider the questions oh, i hate
this guy 28% more than i hate the other guy, so how do i rate each
candidate in range?


It forces no such consideration. If the voter thinks that thought, 
the voter has far more quantitative information than is probably even 
possible. All that Range Voting is is an allowance for fractional 
voting. Almost certainly any sensible voter would start with ranking, 
sorting the candidates into rank order or into ranked sets, the 
simplest being approved and disapproved. If that's all the voter 
wants to do, done. Vote max for approved and min for disapproved. And 
the approved set may be one candidate or none.


(When a majority is required, voting against all candidates is not a 
moot vote. It is a vote, generally, to hold a runoff or maybe even to 
reconsider the entire election, is this office necessary to fill? 
Sometimes we forget that public elections are not the only 
application of voting systems!)


All the voter is doing is distributing voting power. It can be 
distributed in a very simple way or in a more complex and 
sophisticated way. It is up to the voter, and every voter has one 
vote, and one vote only, and may exercise the whole vote or just part 
of it. Voter freedom. I'm amazed at how many people object to it.



  the range rating values are a superset of the
adjacent integer rankings from a ranked-order ballot like one for
Condorcet, IRV, Borda.  in the ranked-order ballot, all the voter has
to decide is who she would vote for in adjacent candidates: ABC.
she doesn't have to decide how much more she likes B over C than how
much A is over B.


That's true. But the voter can vote Range in quite this way. This 
argument would amaze me if I hadn't seen it so many times. Range is 
too hard for voters, supposedly. But, let's back up. I'm not 
recommending diving into public implementation of Range immediately, 
beyond Range 1, or approval. Which is simply Plurality with a freedom 
to multiply approve. Why in the world would we want to prevent this?


Robert's Rules of Order doesn't allow, on written ballots, multiple 
votes, it voids the vote. However, that seems to be an historical 
tradition, and the only reason given is that the vote must be an 
error. How can they count the vote if it's an error. And it's an 
error because it won't be counted. It's possible that there was, at 
some point, some thought that it would violate one person-one vote. 
But it is no more a violation of that, than is preferential voting, 
which allows casting more than one vote. In the end, the voter has 
only one vote to cast in each pairwise election. Plurality requires 
that the voter cast all these votes with only one preferred 
candidate, and to abstain from voting in all other pairs. 
Preferential voting allows the voter to vote in different pairs (but 
the voter can generally vote it just as Plurality), but most 
preferential voting implementations don't allow equal ranking, which 
is an obvious defect.


If rating is supposedly so hard, why don't we notice that requiring a 
voter to rank when the voter has no significant preference is also hard?


Very simple to vote Range if the number of ranks is equal to the 
number of candidates, i.e., it's a Borda ballot and is counted like 
Borda. And the only thing that makes Borda different from Range is 
that generally Borda doesn't allow equal ranking. Why not? The reason 
give, supposedly, is to prevent strategic voting, but that's a 
defective concept applied to Range. Strategic voting, boiled down, is 
a method whereby voters attempt to use the method to gain a preferred outcome.


That's what we want voters to do! The goal of a good voting system is 
to allow their natural preferences to accomplish this, and if a voter 
wants to vote Anybody but Joe, why not?


Various Borda rules have been proposed as to how to treat incomplete 
ranking (and equal ranking, if allowed by the ballot design, is 
considered incomplete ranking). To me, the offensive way is to 
devalue the ballot. That is, the ballot isn't given full value for 
the highest rank, or, alternatively, minimum value for the bottom 
rank. The effect is to weaken the vote. Why? Why should a voter who 
decides to vote no preference between two candidates be assigned less 
voting power in all the *other* pairwise elections?


Very simple concept. Allow equal ranking. It makes just about every 
voting system perform better. It helps Plurality find majorities, to 
the extent that voters use it. Supporters of no-hope candidates may 
use it, thus showing, in the election, true support for their 
candidate (because those votes are now unconstrained by a desire to 
cast an effective vote for election purposes).


Sure, simple 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

I couldn't resist this and another. Silly time!

At 04:15 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:
(I'd written previously)

no slip nor nuttin' else under me kilt.  want me to show you?


You already did. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.

Silly hat, Off.

Robert, if you want to be effective in public debate, I'd suggest 
avoiding setting up an immediate victory by the other side by feeding 
him or her lines like that. In person, face-to-face, people would 
fall over laughing, and whatever value there was in your position 
would be lost. 



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

and FairVote.org will point to experts that strongly advocate IRV.
big fat hairy deel.


They will. Anecdotal. Look, a lot of experts follow the EM list. Have 
been for a long time. Very few who aren't politically committed in 
some way, such as Terry Bouricius, who is actually more of a 
politician than an expert on voting systems, will defend IRV here. I 
can only think of Chris Benham, who is from Australia, and we all 
know what that means. He's upside-down.


(Seriously, Chris is quite knowledgeable, but he's pretty isolated. 
IRV has been considered unacceptable by experts since the 19th 
century, I found criticism from political scientists from that 
century. It was not adopted in Australia because it was an ideal 
system, it was adopted because it saved the day for a party in power, 
eliminating the spoiler effect, defanging minor parties and thus 
eventually killing them.)



whether it's here or on the Burlington blog or longer ago at the
Fairvote site (that i have since gotten tired of), i have never
appealed to authority in evaluating or advocating any method.


It's just a fact, and it's relevant, whether you appeal to it or not. 
FairVote has really poisoned the air, citing Tideman, for example, 
when criticising other methods but never mentioning that Tideman 
considers IRV unacceptable.




I'm thinking over the opposition material. It might look rabid to
someone who isn't aware of the problems,


but i think i *am* aware of the salient problems.


You are only aware of some of the problems, not enough to realize 
that IRV may actually be worse than plurality in some situations. 
Which happen to be most of the implementations, i.e., nonpartisan elections.



  but despite that,
i support the goals that we had in adopting IRV.  i still don't
support correcting IRV by reverting back to FPTP, given that is the
choice presented (the reverted rules would include a delayed-runoff
for less than 40%).


The only problem with the 40% is that it's the wrong margin to be 
looking for. Or it's inadequate. 40%/39% is very different, runoff 
required, than 40%/30%, which is probably an unrecoverable margin. 
Depends. In particular, it depends on data which isn't on the primary 
ballot. Hence, make the primary ballot a preferential ballot, but 
simply use a better method to analyze it.


Or, at least, allow additional approvals in the primary. Count All 
the Votes. Look, Robert, if you can't get behind that slogan, you 
will continue to irritate both the election integrity experts and the 
voting system experts



  and voting security concerns have been
persuasive.  even with IRV, with a reasonably small number of
credible candidates (and assuming the worse case, that write-in is
always the same person, without yet checking), there are a finite
number of ranking permutations, and there can be a ballot for each.
continued below...


I'm going to cut to the chase, here. Robert, you have failed to 
understand what happens in the first counting. All votes in the first 
rank must be counted and reported, period. Even write-in votes must 
be counted, but they can generally be reported as a sum, and only if 
the sum is large enough that it is all for one candidate, would the 
instruction have to go back to the precinct to break down and 
separately report the category. It goes back to all precincts 
reporting any write-in votes! Normally, that would be all of them.


You cannot tell which votes should be reported, in advance, based 
solely on local precinct data. It's quite possible that the winner 
has no votes in the local precinct at all, is just unpopular there. 
Are you saying that dark horses should be ignored, that write-in 
candidates should be ignored?


So, consider Burlington. Three major candidates. How many minor on 
the ballot? Three? That's six, plus write-in. You must report all 
combinations, but you may collapse where there are empty ranks, 
because, with the IRV counting methods, A(blank)B is equivalent to 
AB is equivalent to (blank)AB.


Credible candidate, quite simply, must be ignored by the method. 
Data for any combination of 7 candidates including Write-in, which is 
lumped tentatively, must be tabulated into all of the relevant 
patterns (after collapse of equivalent ones as described). So with 
RCV, three-rank, you would have:


three candidate combinations:
7*6*5 = 210.

two candidate combinations:
7*6 = 42.

bullet votes or equivalent:
7

Total 258 piles. Now, go to San Francisco. 23 candidates on the 
ballot, plus write-ins. I'm not even going to do the math. Simpler to 
just transmit the raw ballot images, with computers. Or the counting 
is done at each precinct, centrally directed, and it is far more 
complex than precinct summable methods. Approval, very simple. 
Bucklin all ranks can be counted and reported as sums. Range the 
same. IRV. Arrggh. No. Real life elections in the U.S.? Major delays. 
When an error is 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-20 Thread Terry Bouricius
Abd has repeated an erroneous statement about Nicolaus Tideman's 
assessment of voting methods. Abd wrote:

snipFairVote has really poisoned the air, citing Tideman, for example, 
when criticising other methods but never mentioning that Tideman considers 
IRV unacceptable. snip

Tideman does NOT consider IRV unacceptable (If you ask him, I believe he 
will say he favors it in real world implementations). To set the record 
straight, I will paste the rebuttal I sent to this list when Warren Smith 
made the same mistake last year.

Terry Bouricius


On page 238 [in his book _Collective Decisions and Voting_]Tideman has a
chart with five categories summarizing his analysis of methods...
First is Not supportable which includes
Borda, Range, Dodgson, Copeland, Coombs and Est. centrality.

The next category is Arguably inferior to maxmin which includes
Condorcet, Simp. Dodgson, Nanson, Bucklin, Black, Young, and Wt. 
Condorcet.

The third category is Supportable if ranking is infeasible which 
includes
Plurality, Approval, and Two-ballot majority.

The fourth category is Supportable if a matrix is uncalculable which 
includes
only Alternative vote [IRV]

The last category is Supportable if a matrix of majorities is calculable 
which includes
Maxmin, Ranked Pairs, Schulze, Alt. Schwartz and Alt. Smith.

Warren [now Abd] is assuming that a matrix is always calculable and thus 
the
supportable category that includes only IRV is in fact null. However, that
is not what Tideman is arguing (or why would he create the category if it
was always empty)? Elsewhere he discusses the practical limitations of
voting methods used for public elections including ease of voter
acceptance and argues that a hypothetical improvement of a system that
requires complexities such as matrices may be impractical in large scale
elections. He writes on page 240 If it is feasible to require voters to
rank options, then much more sophisticated processing is possible.
However, it is conceivable that it would be feasible to require voters to
rank options but not feasible to require vote-processors to produce a
matrix of majorities. In this event the Alternative vote is supportable.


- Original Message - 
From: Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a...@lomaxdesign.com
To: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com; EM Methods 
election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Wednesday, January 20, 2010 11:54 AM
Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)


At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:
and FairVote.org will point to experts that strongly advocate IRV.
big fat hairy deel.

They will. Anecdotal. Look, a lot of experts follow the EM list. Have
been for a long time. Very few who aren't politically committed in
some way, such as Terry Bouricius, who is actually more of a
politician than an expert on voting systems, will defend IRV here. I
can only think of Chris Benham, who is from Australia, and we all
know what that means. He's upside-down.

(Seriously, Chris is quite knowledgeable, but he's pretty isolated.
IRV has been considered unacceptable by experts since the 19th
century, I found criticism from political scientists from that
century. It was not adopted in Australia because it was an ideal
system, it was adopted because it saved the day for a party in power,
eliminating the spoiler effect, defanging minor parties and thus
eventually killing them.)

whether it's here or on the Burlington blog or longer ago at the
Fairvote site (that i have since gotten tired of), i have never
appealed to authority in evaluating or advocating any method.

It's just a fact, and it's relevant, whether you appeal to it or not.
FairVote has really poisoned the air, citing Tideman, for example,
when criticising other methods but never mentioning that Tideman
considers IRV unacceptable.


I'm thinking over the opposition material. It might look rabid to
someone who isn't aware of the problems,

but i think i *am* aware of the salient problems.

You are only aware of some of the problems, not enough to realize
that IRV may actually be worse than plurality in some situations.
Which happen to be most of the implementations, i.e., nonpartisan 
elections.

   but despite that,
i support the goals that we had in adopting IRV.  i still don't
support correcting IRV by reverting back to FPTP, given that is the
choice presented (the reverted rules would include a delayed-runoff
for less than 40%).

The only problem with the 40% is that it's the wrong margin to be
looking for. Or it's inadequate. 40%/39% is very different, runoff
required, than 40%/30%, which is probably an unrecoverable margin.
Depends. In particular, it depends on data which isn't on the primary
ballot. Hence, make the primary ballot a preferential ballot, but
simply use a better method to analyze it.

Or, at least, allow additional approvals in the primary. Count All
the Votes. Look, Robert, if you can't get behind that slogan, you
will continue to irritate both the election integrity

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality ( Kristofer Munsterhjelm )

2010-01-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 01:13 PM 1/20/2010, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

At 09:09 AM 1/17/2010, Chris Benham wrote:

Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote (17 Jan 2010):

To me, it seems that the method becomes Approval-like when (number of
graduations) is less than (number of candidates). When that is the case,
you *have* to rate some candidates equal, unless you opt not to rate
them at all.


Sure. However, in practical methods in the near future, not rating 
them at all is equivalent to bottom-rating. And all methods on the 
table equal-rank candidates not ranked.


In my view, preventing voters from equal ranking is preventing voters 
from expressing valuable information. However, not allowing them to 
rank when they have a significant preference also conceals valuable 
information. There is a compromise, such that information that the 
voter cannot express is of minimal significance.



That won't make much of a difference when the number of candidates is
huge (100 or so), but then, rating 100 candidates would be a pain.


Unless I can just lump them as I like. Bucklin, one of the early 
elections, had something like 100 candidates. People got excited 
about a method that would allow sincere voting without a spoiler 
effect and the method apparently worked. Three-rank ballot, 
probably. That means four ranks when we count bottom. Very simple to 
vote on 100 candidates.


1. Vote for favorite first rank.
2. Vote for any others first rank if you have difficulty deciding 
between them, i.e., what is really being done is defining a favorite 
*class* of candidates roughly equal in value.
3. Vote for any candidates you'd be happy to see election (not just 
merely not unhappy), but not favored, in second rank.
4. Vote for any candidates you would prefer to a runoff being held, 
in the last rank. Any rank may also be empty, and that conveys 
information about preference strength.
5. Don't recognize the candidate? Probably you don't vote for the 
candidate. Don't like the candidate, wouldn't want your vote to avoid 
a runoff? Don't vote for the candidate.


A rough equivalent of this ballot and voting approach would be 
Range4, with the value of 1 missing, you can't vote it. And range 
analysis could then be done. If the value of 1 is inserted as a 
Disapproved but better than worst category, then you'd get true 
range analysis, and if there is a significant difference between the 
Range winner and the Bucklin winner, I'd suggest a runoff might be held.


Contrary to the immediate reaction of many voting systems students, 
the Range winner, in a real runoff, if the data is accurate, has a 
natural advantage. It's because of differential turnout.



 I'd
say it would be better to just have plain yes/no Approval for a first
round, then pick the 5-10 most approved for a second round (using
Range, Condorcet, whatever). Or use minmax approval or PAV or somesuch,
as long as it homes in on the likely winners of a full vote.


While 5-10 for the next round sounds good, it normally would also 
eliminated one of the major advantages of runoff voting: closer 
examination of the candidates remaining.


*If the top two are well chosen*, it's beneficial to have only two on 
the ballot. However, there are other possibilities. As an example, 
the candidates could be listed on the ballot in order of range 
ranking, so voters have the information from the previous ballot to 
guide them and may then vote as strategically as they like. Strategic 
voting in range is an expression of sincere preference strength in 
relevant races, that's been overlooked. It never involves preference reversal.


If somehow the wrong candidate makes it into the top two (quite 
unlikely with a good choice algorithm, though the possibility 
certainly increases with many, many candidates), write-in votes can 
be allowed in the runoff. If there is a missing candidate with 
significant preference strength, a write-in can win a runoff, and 
it's happened. It won't happen unless there is sincere and 
significant preference strength, and the vast majority of the time, 
the write-ins will be irrelevant, and if the runoff method is 
spoiler-free, like Bucklin as a simple example, no problem. Vote for 
your write-in and still cast an effective vote in the real election.



Simply using plain Approval to reduce the field to the top x point scorers
who then compete in the final round seems unsatifactory to me because
of the  Rich Party incentive (clone problem) for parties to field 
x candidates;

and because of the tempting Push-over (turkey raising) strategy incentive.


Sure. However, Rich Party and Turkey Raising don't work with approval 
methods, beyond the communication advantages rich parties may have 
through greater media access. Bucklin seems to me to be a 
much-neglected approval method, with real implementation history, 
that behaves like approval, and whenever an election is close with 
more than two candidates, all ranks will be added in, so it *is* 
approval; but the 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-20 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax



Sent from my iPhone

On Jan 20, 2010, at 1:35 PM, Terry Bouricius ter...@burlingtontelecom.net 
 wrote:



Abd has repeated an erroneous statement about Nicolaus Tideman's
assessment of voting methods. Abd wrote:

snipFairVote has really poisoned the air, citing Tideman, for  
example,
when criticising other methods but never mentioning that Tideman  
considers

IRV unacceptable. snip

Tideman does NOT consider IRV unacceptable.


I won't say that again unless I confirm it. I was repeating what I'd  
seen, with quotes, so I'm not exactly retracting yet, but I sure will  
check it out. Thanks, Terry.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-20 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 20, 2010, at 11:23 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Variation on previous post. Silly time!

At 02:31 PM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


We already knew that.


you do?  you keep saying that you can see it.



Silly hat, Off.

Robert, if you want to be effective in public debate,


what makes you think i'm not effective?  do you actually think you  
were effective?


i won't slap on the argumentum verbosium and explode the debate  
about a single testable issue (like how many piles one needs if there  
are 3 candidates) into pages and pages, that when i responded, my  
post was rejected by the list server as too large.



I'd suggest avoiding setting up an immediate victory by the other  
side by feeding him or her lines like that.


you're the one feeding lines.  who brought up the slip showing in  
the first place?  how does one respond when facing: Your slip is  
showing, now onto a verbose response that does not speak to the core  
factual issues at all.


you and Kathy had no victory (if that is the way you like looking  
at it).  where it is about fact (derived or historically supported)  
regarding the focussed issue, you haven't done anything to touch it.


the fact is, transmitting the content (to a central counting  
location) of *every ballot* is the transfer of a finite amount of  
information.  that is even *more* general than sorting to piles and  
transmitting the tallies for piles.


but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation  
of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite  
number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or  
Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's  
showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 40.  for  
N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is


   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=1

not

   N-1
P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
   n=0

which is appears to be the formula you and Kathy continue to insist  
is correct.  and whether Kathy has an MS in Mathematics or not,  
whether you do or not, this error is demonstrable.  you and Kathy  
continue to insist that there is a consequential difference between  
ranking all candidates and ranking all but 1 and leaving one  
candidate unranked and i continue to say there is no consequential  
difference.  this is a difference of falsifiable claims that form a  
dichotomy.we can test which claim is correct.


In person, face-to-face, people would fall over laughing, and  
whatever value there was in your position would be lost.



you've never used humor to make a point?  or to make clear the  
lameness of an irrelevant reference?


whether one responds to an irrelevant distraction with humor or not  
changes nothing regarding the core issues.


certainly if a ridiculously large number of candidates are on the  
ballot, manually separating ballots into piles (without grouping  
together minor or non-credible candidates) is not practical.  even  
with 4 salient candidates, 40 piles gets pretty nasty for sorting by  
*hand*.  but 40 is still a pretty small number for a computer and a  
modern network.


a national election with 3 credible candidates can easily be  
precinct summable with 9 salient piles and 31 less important  
piles.  it doesn't matter if it is IRV, Condorcet, Borda or what.   
the issue of summing pile count is not dependent on what tabulation  
method is used (and what, *i* think, should be what the debate is  
about).


neither you nor Kathy have shown *any* problem of precinct  
summability regarding IRV or any other ranked-ballot method.


not that i am a defender of IRV.  but, you haven't laid a hand on it  
regarding precinct summability.  IRV has a few pathologies, which i  
think i understand better than either you or Kathy, simply from the  
lame and partisan arguments (and wholly verbose) i read coming from  
that direction.


even though *now* Kathy seems to be paying some attention to  
Condorcet, before this last week, i haven't noticed any such  
attention about that from her.  it was always just how bad IRV is,  
and that it's worse than any other method, including FPTP.  and when  
she (or you) says that, then i am convinced that she (or you) are  
simply anti-IRV partisans that don't really consider what the  
*commonly* *known* problems are that associated with the traditional  
FPTP (or even 2-round with runoff) methods for which motivated us to  
adopt IRV in the first place.


so, before pointing out that someone's slip is showing, it might be  
safer to adjust where one's own fig leaf is hanging.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread robert bristow-johnson


okay, Abd ul, i once got suckered into responding to a big long thing  
you made in response to me.  you probably seen it, but the list  
hasn't because it exceeded some size limit.  so i'm gonna snip at the  
first place to respond and i'll ask that the next issue area get its  
separate email thread (we might even spawn new subject lines).  i  
just can't deal with size explosion to this degree.


On Jan 17, 2010, at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 01:44 AM 1/15/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

but the problem with considering *more* than pure ranking (Range) is
that it requires too much information from the voter.  and the
problem with *less* (Approval or FPTP) is that it obtains too little
information from the voter.


There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range  
requires too much information from the voter.


well, it does force the voter to consider the questions oh, i hate  
this guy 28% more than i hate the other guy, so how do i rate each  
candidate in range?  the range rating values are a superset of the  
adjacent integer rankings from a ranked-order ballot like one for  
Condorcet, IRV, Borda.  in the ranked-order ballot, all the voter has  
to decide is who she would vote for in adjacent candidates: ABC.   
she doesn't have to decide how much more she likes B over C than how  
much A is over B.  one is a quick set of qualitative decisions.  the  
other makes it a quantitative issue, and that's when a lot of us get  
out our dartboard.  i don't think making threshold decision based on  
the precise sum of a bunch of noisy numbers (which is what Range is  
when we use our dartboards to score a candidate) does much other than  
to add the means of the noisy numbers and a sum of zero-mean random  
numbers which throws a little bit of dice into the mix before using  
the threshold comparison and determining the winner.


so it requires thinking that we wouldn't have to do otherwise.  if we  
don't feel like thinking that seriously, it becomes a big noisy  
threshold on the means of stable ranks.  that's sorta like Borda and  
does become the equivalent if people's evaluations of candidates  
sorta linear.



First of all, Approval is Range, simply the most basic Range method.


it's Range with 1-bit binary values.

So what you have is a contradiction: Range requires both too much  
and too little information. Surely it depends on the specific Range  
implementation.


yes it does.   of course the answer is (if i may appeal to an audio  
image) that what we *normally* mean when we say Range is were the  
sliders for each candidate are either continuous or have many  
discrete values (say 10 or 100).


a two-position slider is what we call a switch. requires one bit of  
information.  that's getting qualitatively different.  either you are  
at the minimum number of levels (or bits of information in the slider  
position) or you're not.


perhaps a 3-position slider can be Actively Disapprove, no opinion  
- neutral, and Actively Approve


perhaps a 4-position slider can be Actively Disapprove, no opinion  
- neutral, and Actively Approve and Hey, I really like this guy!


perhaps a 5-position slider can be This guy is crap, Actively  
Disapprove, no opinion - neutral, and Actively Approve and Hey,  
I really like this guy!


we can continue on like this with more discrete levels and all we'll  
get are gradations of the above.  it's all a matter of degree.


but the 2-position slider is a 1-bit piece of information:  
No,Yes, that's the minimum a voter has to judge.  that's  
qualitatively different.  here's why:  with the multi-level (3 or  
more), then order has to be considered with candidates that you  
approve or disapprove.


but the multi-level or continuous slider (3+) requires *more* than  
just ordering information (who is preferred to whom?), it requires  
*spacing* information.  like i hate candidate D worse than i hate C  
whom i dislike more than B whom i like less than A.  you have to  
decide that D is twice as badder than C than C is badder than B or  
some other value judgement.  what if you just don't feel like making  
such a precise judgement?  then you get your dartboard.




--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-17 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 5:02 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:


robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 16, 2010, at 3:41 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:



Exactly as I tried to point out to you, you were either disallowing
voters to rank only two candidates or to rank all three.
no, it has nothing at all to do with allowing or disallowing the 
voters to

  I see I was
correct and you are disallowing voters to rank only two candidates and
have, as Abd ul also pointed out to you, left 3 choose 2 or 6 possible
choices out of your list.
because all unmarked candidates are tied for last place, when there 
is only one unmarked candidate, there is *no* consequential 
difference between leaving that candidate unmarked or marking that 
candidate last.


Is that true in IRV? Consider a vote of the sort:

A  B

where A and B are eliminated. Then this would be an empty vote, I 
think, and so be removed from the count, whereas if it had been


A  B  C

it would count as one point for C.


now lemme see, if there are three candidates, how are two of them 
eliminated before the IRV final round?


Ah, I see. The only way for that to happen is if both B and C tie for 
last, in which case A wins by default.


Thus it only matters if there are more than three candidates, i.e. when 
both ABC and AB votes are truncated.


think about it little bit, Kristofer, it *is* a useful fiction to leave 
the 2 bottom candidates (of 5) out of consideration (so one can get a 
grip of what happened in Burlington VT in 2009), but once you've done 
that (and you're considering only what happens between the remaining 3), 
the 9 numbers that are the only tallies you need to consider *any* 
counting scenario, IRV, Condorcet, Plurality of 1st choice, tallies for 
1st or 2nd choice (some people in Burlington have suggested that as the 
number to use to determine the weakest candidate to eliminate in an IRV 
round), whatever, are:



  1332  MKW
   767  MWK
   455  M
  2043  KMW
   371  KWM
   568  K
  1513  WMK
   495  WKM
  1289  W


with exactly those three candidates in consideration, what consequential 
difference would it make in IRV (or any other rule of tabulation) if the 
[1332  MKW] pile was split into two piles; [MKW] and [MK] that 
totaled 1332?  those 9 numbers could certainly be determined in 
individual precincts and meaningfully summed at City Hall or the 
campaign headquarters of either candidate.


I'm not sure if it would be equivalent in Borda, however. Some ways of 
extending Borda to incomplete (truncated) ballots suggest that you give 
the last candidate 1 point, the next to last 2, etc, so that for


A  B

B gets one point and A two, whereas for

A  B  C

A gets three.

It would also make a difference if the election method in question uses 
no opinion the way Warren's Range extension does: that no opinion is 
to provide no information at all (alters neither the numerator nor 
denominator of the average).


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:

we can continue on like this with more discrete levels and all we'll get 
are gradations of the above.  it's all a matter of degree.


but the 2-position slider is a 1-bit piece of information: No,Yes, 
that's the minimum a voter has to judge.  that's qualitatively 
different.  here's why:  with the multi-level (3 or more), then order 
has to be considered with candidates that you approve or disapprove.


but the multi-level or continuous slider (3+) requires *more* than just 
ordering information (who is preferred to whom?), it requires *spacing* 
information.  like i hate candidate D worse than i hate C whom i 
dislike more than B whom i like less than A.  you have to decide that D 
is twice as badder than C than C is badder than B or some other value 
judgement.  what if you just don't feel like making such a precise 
judgement?  then you get your dartboard.


To me, it seems that the method becomes Approval-like when (number of 
graduations) is less than (number of candidates). When that is the case, 
you *have* to rate some candidates equal, unless you opt not to rate 
them at all.


That won't make much of a difference when the number of candidates is 
huge (100 or so), but then, rating 100 candidates would be a pain. I'd 
say it would be better to just have plain yes/no Approval for a first 
round, then pick the 5-10 most approved for a second round (using 
Range, Condorcet, whatever). Or use minmax approval or PAV or somesuch, 
as long as it homes in on the likely winners of a full vote.


I guess that if you (hypothetically speaking) like Range, you could 
argue that while there's a dartboard effect, the noise is unbiased and 
so will cancel itself out given enough voters: the voters may not hit 
exactly at the satisfaction point, but close enough.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread Kathy Dopp
For the record, I like approval voting and think it would be among the
best, if not the best, first step as an alternative voting method to
plurality.  However, I also think Condorcet is OK as long as voters
are not required to rank all choices, to alleviate the point Abd ul
mentions below somewhat.  Really, the only methods I would object to
are the fundamentally unfair ones like IRV/STV that treat voters'
votes differentially and thus produce very undesirable election
results and remove the rights of some voters to fully participate.
Approval, if courts OK it, is by far the simplest to count, audit,
explain to voters, etc. and is probably the best first step.  Using
IRV/STV as a first step may turn off people to alternative electoral
methods for a very long time after they realize how deeply they've
been misled on how it works, its effects, etc.

I am now going to, for the most part, soon drop out of participation
in this list again for the Spring semester at college.

Kathy

On Sun, Jan 17, 2010 at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
a...@lomaxdesign.com wrote:
 At 01:44 AM 1/15/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

 but the problem with considering *more* than pure ranking (Range) is
 that it requires too much information from the voter.  and the
 problem with *less* (Approval or FPTP) is that it obtains too little
 information from the voter.

 There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range requires too
 much information from the voter. First of all, Approval is Range, simply the
 most basic Range method. So what you have is a contradiction: Range
 requires both too much and too little information. Surely it depends on the
 specific Range implementation.

 But there is a more fundamental error: that of requirement. Voters may
 vote in Approval, and Range, as they would vote in Plurality, if they want,
 and for most voters, this is a simple and powerful strategy. If they favor a
 frontrunner, and if there are only two frontrunners (the normal situation!),
 whatever else they would do would be moot for election purposes. But they
 could cast votes to show support, which has other salutary effects. That, in
 fact, is why Warren Smith calls Range an incubator for minor parties. It
 allows them to show their natural support, neither more nor less.

 The only issue about voting strategy arises in a real three-way race,
 which is not common. Most voters, however, would be reasonably served by a
 very simple strategy. Vote first for your favorite candidate, no strategy
 necessary or even useful. Then consider the frontrunners, however many there
 are, it's the set of candidates that you think have a prayer of winning, and
 vote for your favorite of them. (in Approval, that's it, in Range, it means
 vote max or maybe just short of max). Is your favorite one of the
 frontrunners?.

 Vote minimum rating (i.e., in Approval, don't vote at all for) the worst
 candidate, with no strategic considerations at all. Vote similarly for the
 worst frontrunner: minimum rating or just a tad higher if the system allows
 it.

 And then where do you vote for the rest of the candidates, the ones in the
 middle? Well, pay attention first to any remaining frontrunners. (In most
 elections, there aren't any left, but we are now talking about a situation
 where there are three or more, and we should remember that this is rare.) My
 own conclusion from study of the game theory involved is that possible
 expected improvement from seriously optimizing Range votes is small at best
 over simply voting sincere ratings, and as long as preference order isn't
 reversed, it's all likely to average out. At worst, from clear exaggeration
 in order to gain some strategic advantage, it's possible to cast a vote that
 will leave behind serious regret once you know the outcome.

 When you have ranked the frontrunners where it seems right, then fill in any
 remaining candidates you want to rate. If it gets crowded, equal rank a
 candidate being added with the one already ranked.

 Rating equals ranking with the option of equal ranking.

 Equal preference strength expression (i.e., if one spreads the candidates
 through the rating space evenly) is Borda count. If you don't like that, if
 it seems to be off, then fix it. Spread some ratings apart, which
 necessarily compresses some. Don't hesitate to equal rank if you have any
 difficulty deciding which of two candidates are better. The fact that you
 have difficulty is a clear indication that you don't have a strong
 preference!

 I would not spend a lot of time actually doing the ranking/rating. The hard
 part is learning enough about the candidates to have a foundation for
 opinions. So if I don't have enough information to do that, I don't have
 strong preferences! and so voting is easy, if I simply express that. I can
 spread my vote over the full range if I think that my intuition might be
 valuable (it can be! -- but it may also be vulnerable to media
 manipulation). My choice. Range 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-17 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 03:01 AM 1/17/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 17, 2010, at 12:53 AM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


There is a common error here, which is to assume that Range
requires too much information from the voter.


well, it does force the voter to consider the questions oh, i hate
this guy 28% more than i hate the other guy, so how do i rate each
candidate in range?  the range rating values are a superset of the
adjacent integer rankings from a ranked-order ballot like one for
Condorcet, IRV, Borda.


Part of the problem is the way in which Range has been presented. It 
isn't really rating candidates, though that can be part of the 
process. It's *voting.*


The simplest way to describe Range, and to think about it, is that it 
is Approval Voting with fractional votes allowed. Not required.


There is a whole debate among students of Range about using average 
vote rather than sum of votes. The difference is that with sum of 
votes, we have a traditional Approval voting system, which always 
uses sum of votes. Not average vote. (Average vote is meaningless, 
really, unless the ballot asks for Yes or No or Approve/Disapprove 
for each candidate). Average vote doesn't consider majority at all. 
Naturally, I support sum of votes, and though average vote is 
interesting (in terms of understanding the future of a candidate), it 
isn't *voting*, which in it's basic form, is seeking for a majority 
of voters to vote for a candidate for the candidate to win. Is voting 
1/100 vote for a candidate voting for a candidate?


I would try to make ballot instructions make it clear that the voter 
is casting fractional votes, and probably shouldn't vote for a 
candidate at all if the voter isn't willing to support the candidate 
against others. That makes the decision much easier.



  in the ranked-order ballot, all the voter has
to decide is who she would vote for in adjacent candidates: ABC.
she doesn't have to decide how much more she likes B over C than how
much A is over B.  one is a quick set of qualitative decisions.  the
other makes it a quantitative issue, and that's when a lot of us get
out our dartboard.


Sure. But you don't have to make those quantitative decisions if you 
don't want to. It's optional, and, in fact, I prefer that voters not 
cast fractional votes unless they are easy for them to decide.



  i don't think making threshold decision based on
the precise sum of a bunch of noisy numbers (which is what Range is
when we use our dartboards to score a candidate) does much other than
to add the means of the noisy numbers and a sum of zero-mean random
numbers which throws a little bit of dice into the mix before using
the threshold comparison and determining the winner.


The numbers can be noisy, but surely you know that adding certain 
kinds of noise can improve the accuracy of a feedback system! They 
aren't actually noise, they are noisy. The averages provide 
information, and the very fact of the existence of fractional votes 
-- even just one! -- improves the utility of the system, that's been shown.




so it requires thinking that we wouldn't have to do otherwise.  if we
don't feel like thinking that seriously, it becomes a big noisy
threshold on the means of stable ranks.  that's sorta like Borda and
does become the equivalent if people's evaluations of candidates
sorta linear.


First of all, Approval is Range, simply the most basic Range method.


it's Range with 1-bit binary values.


Yup. Range 1, I call it, which means that there are two possible 
votes, generally with one being the default. Approval voting is 
Plurality voting, with the *option* of voting for more than one. Most 
voters, under normal conditions in the U.S., don't need to do it!



So what you have is a contradiction: Range requires both too much
and too little information. Surely it depends on the specific Range
implementation.


yes it does.   of course the answer is (if i may appeal to an audio
image) that what we *normally* mean when we say Range is were the
sliders for each candidate are either continuous or have many
discrete values (say 10 or 100).


Only Smith considers a continuous slider, and I prefer, simply, to 
consider that what separates Range from Approval is the ability to 
cast fractional votes. Freedom from the voter. Sure: if you have 
freedom you have more choices and, gosh, you might even be tempted to *think*!


Tell me, do you want voters to think or do you think of voting 
systems as a device that extracts information from voters without 
them thinking about it? And making actual decisions?



a two-position slider is what we call a switch. requires one bit of
information.  that's getting qualitatively different.  either you are
at the minimum number of levels (or bits of information in the slider
position) or you're not.


And all the switches are off by default. So, don't want to do much work?

First option: don't vote at all! Leave it to others who know more and 
care more. And this 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-17 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
Cutting to the chase, the fundamental error has been to assume that  
write-in or so-called inconsequential candidates can be batch- 
eliminated before having results from the whole election. No precinct  
knows what can be eliminated until it has the results from other  
precincts for the first round. Further a method must accomodate not  
just a most-common scenario but also all possible scenarios. Runoff  
voting in general encourages candidate counts to increase. Cf. San  
Francisco.


We are talking about the matrix size necessary to fully canvass an IRV  
election centrally from initial data provided by each precinct. That  
initial data might categorize all write-candidates into a single pile,  
but the risk is that if reports from other precincts indicate possible  
significance, it would be necessary to ask the precincts to tabulate  
the write-in pile. If you did this with so-called minor candidates,  
you'd see a lawsuit, which is less likely with write-ins. 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Dave Ketchum

On Jan 15, 2010, at 10:51 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

Message: 3
Date: Fri, 15 Jan 2010 22:05:58 -0500
From: Dave Ketchum da...@clarityconnect.com
To: Juho juho4...@yahoo.co.uk

On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:46 PM, Juho wrote:

On Jan 14, 2010, at 2:13 AM, Dave Ketchum wrote:

On Jan 13, 2010, at 4:49 AM, Juho wrote:

On Jan 13, 2010, at 9:14 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


it still is a curiosity to me how, historically, some leaders and
proponents of election reform thunked up the idea to have a
ranked-order ballot and then took that good idea and married it
to the IRV protocol.  with the 200 year old Condorcet idea in
existence, why would they do that?


1) The basic idea of IRV is in some sense natural. It is like a
street fight. The weakest players are regularly kicked out and
they must give up. I'm not saying that this would lead to good
results but at least this game is understandable to most people.
Condorcet on the other hand is more like a mathematical equation,


Yet Condorcet is simple to count and precinct-summable, monotonic, and
treats all voters' votes equally, unlike IRV/STV which is virtually
impossible to manually count, requires a mind-boggling number of piles
and subpiles to count it and requires that all late-counted ballots
are ready to count centrally, or the entire long tedious process has
to be restarted.


and the details of the most complex Condorcet variants may be too
much for most voters. Here I'm not saying that each voter (and not
even each legislator) should understand all the details of their
voting system. The basic Condorcet winner rule is however a simple
enough principle to be explained to all. But it may be that IRV is
easier to market (to the legislators and voters) from this point
of view.


The organization promoting IRV/STV is very well-funded and invests a
lot of capital into highly misleading local advertising campaigns in
order to promote its adoption.  I could send this list some
information on that if anyone is interested.  I don't think that any
group promoting a fair, equitable, auditable alternative method like
Condorcet or others has put forth such a well-funded campaign have
they?


When there is a CW in Condorcet, the CW has won in comparison with
each other candidate.  While a few may like X or Z enough better to
have given such top ranking, the fact that all the voters together
prefer the CW over each other should count, and does with  
Condorcet.


Else there is a cycle in Condorcet.  Perhaps the following Minimum
Margins Method Condorcet variant should be used to establish
Condorcet's preferability over other methods.  Then let other
variants compete with this one before finally deciding which to  
use.


Minimum Margins Method:  Consider the cycle, such as ABCA, and
the margins that create it, such as 60A30B, 40B20C, 21C20A.
Delete the weakest margins as many times as needed to destroy the
cycle - in this case A becoming the CW (note that if one CA voter
had voted AC in  this election, A would have become CW with no
cycle).


Great idea. Is this Dave Ketchum speaking above?  Very simple and
logically coherent plan.  Thanks for sharing.  Could it be possible
that this plan would ever not work? (I.e. same margins?)


I did this, though suspecting the idea already has a variant name.   
The adoption is intentionally two steps:
 1.  Use this variant to easily prove there is a Condorcet  
variant ready to compete against such as IRV.
 2.  If there is a better variant, even though likely more  
complex, let it compete against this one.


Same margins is a possibility requiring a response be attended to  
before actual use.  At proposal time the possibility needs mentioning  
- I see nothing more needed at that time (probably delete them one at  
a time in some specified order).




When I see this kind of scenarios I'm always tempted to ask the
question if it is necessary to limit the scope to the top cycle
members or if one can allow also the others win (when the cyclic
opinions in the top cycle are strong). I find also that approach to
be a working solution for many election types (although many have
indicated that they disagree with this).

Note that this method breaks the cycle at the point where the  
smallest
number of ballots being voted differently would have broken the  
cycle.


Note that weaker candidates are unlikely to get enough votes to be
part of a cycle - being weak they get few high rank votes.


Yes, one could certainly say that this allows the top cycle to prevail
by breaking the weakest link where weakest is defined as the smallest
margin in this case.  This minimum margins method is so logically
correct and fair.


2) IRV is easier to count manually. Condorcet gets quite tedious


Whomever said this obviously hasn't ever counted any IRV or STV
elections manually in a contest with a substantial number of
candidates and voters.  Condorcet is orders of magnitude simpler to
count than is IRV because there can never be more than n x n 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Juho

On Jan 16, 2010, at 5:51 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


On Jan 14, 2010, at 2:13 AM, Dave Ketchum wrote:

On Jan 13, 2010, at 4:49 AM, Juho wrote:



2) IRV is easier to count manually. Condorcet gets quite tedious



to count manually when the number of candidates and voters goes
up. One can use some tricks and shortcuts to speed up manual


Condorcet is SO much easier and quicker and simpler to count than IRV
if one simply tallies one n x n matrix for each precinct and sums the
corresponding positions for all the precincts.  No need to wait for
all the absentee and provisional ballots, no need for centralized
counting, no need to sort and resort ballots into dozens of piles of
ballots, or even worse with STV keep track of which portion of which
ballot goes into which pile (tearing or cutting up the ballots would
help in that manual counting nightmare.)



Condorcet counting but IRV probably still beats it from this point
of view. Manual counting was the only way to count for a long
time. Nowadays we have computers and Condorcet tabulation should
thus be no problem at all (at least in places where computers are
available). But this is one reason why IRV has taken an early  
lead.


When an election district has only one polling place, life is  
simple.


Yes. Another point against IRV/STV is no scalability of manual
counting. Condorcet is infinitely scalable since it is as simple to
manually count dozens or hundreds of precincts as it is to count one,
without moving all the ballots to one central location.


When talking about history and the early lead of IRV I referred to the  
times when both ballot reading and recording as well as summing up the  
results to piles or matrixes and all the way up to declaring the final  
results was manual, i.e. before the time of computers. It seems that I  
assumed that telephone or telegraph was already invented when I  
referred at some point also to the option of local counting of IRV  
results with only centralized control of that counting process  
(=advice from the central counting office on which candidates to  
eliminate next etc.).


IRV has at least a tradition of being counted manually in this way.  
I'm not aware of any similar Condorcet tradition in large elections. I  
believe already Ramon Llull had a simple sequential calculation method  
but one would need some enhancements to that method if one wants to  
cover the most popular Condorcent methods.


The problem that I expected in Condorcet (variants that require more  
info than what the Llull process uses) is the size of the matrix and  
the possible need to have some explicit matrix (or several, e.g. on  
paper) where the results are collected when the ballots are read one  
by one. In IRV it is possible to put the ballots in different piles  
since IRV takes into account only the top (non-eliminated) candidate  
of each ballot at one point in time during the counting process. In  
Condorcet, if one wants to count the full matrix, each ballot  
influences multiple entries in the matrix, so the ballots themselves  
can not be used as tools to mark the number of points in some entry in  
the matrix (unless doing the whole process sequentially, counting one  
part of the matrix at each round).


From counting verification point of view the explicit physical  
ballots may be easier to track during the counting process than  
numeric values (or ticks) in the matrix.


I believe a typical manual IRV counting process uses at most as many  
piles as there are candidates a one point in time (each counter having  
his/her own piles is not a problem since the piles are physically  
summable) while a Condorcet counting process might use n*n matrix  
entries.


(jumping to another topic) From voting security point of view the  
summability of Condorcet results offers better protection of voter  
privacy since individual votes can not be identified any more after  
they have been once included in the matrix (that contains sufficient  
information for most Condorcet methods to calculate the final results  
in some central location). In IRV it is more practical to store the  
actual ballots, not e.g. the number of votes per each permutation of  
candidates, so the individual votes may be visible to all the  
verifiers, maybe also to all in Internet.


Juho






Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-16 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 09:47 AM 1/15/2010, Kathy Dopp wrote:

Your steady stream of false claims about me in your
recent emails show us much more about yourself than reveal anything
about me.


To those with eyes, most everything we write reveals much about us. 
However, Kathy, I suggest you let others defend you; correct factual 
errors, if they matter, but don't get caught in the personal 
conflicts, behave as the professional you are. As an expert in your 
field, you will always encounter ignorant objections and attacks.


I think it was important for you to point out that you are 
non-partisan in your work, and I also don't believe that you are 
partisan on the issue of voting systems, beyond what your expertise 
has led you to understand, you are partisan on issues that make 
maintaining election integrity more difficult. And you have become, 
therefore, somewhat of an advocate of not adopting or of dropping such systems.


But that kind of partisanship is common with experts.

To apply this to a question that sometimes comes up, the issue of how 
important strong preferences are. Are strong preferences the result 
of expertise, or of fanaticism? Opponents of Range Voting, which 
respects expressed preference strength, often seem to assume that 
those with strong preferences are partisan fanatics. But is this a 
sane assumption, is it true, on average?


The same line of thinking causes people to assume that there is 
something wrong with low turnout in runoff elections, because those 
who vote are those who care enough to take the trouble to vote. I can 
assume that those who care are not necessarily a fair sample of the 
entire electorate, so, indeed, they may make decisions that would not 
be made by the entire electorate, if you forced the latter to vote. 
(They do this in Australia, actually.)


But which decisions are better for the society? By definition, those 
who don't care as much have less of a stake and less concern about 
the outcome, and, on average, they have less knowledge about the 
implications of each alternative.


One of those expressing complaint about low turnout in runoffs notes 
that it allegedly favors Republicans. If that were true, I'd hasten 
to check out the Republican party. It would be a sign that it was the 
party of those with more knowledge! But it's not generally true; in 
some circumstances, though, the Republicans may be better organized, 
and perhaps this is even due to better funding.


But the solution isn't to use voting systems that force everyone to 
vote, which merely makes results *even more* susceptible to 
manipulation by those with the most funding. The solution is to 
organize the people directly, for the people have resources that are 
even better than money, and more powerful, *if organized.*


Poor people can generally turn out to vote, and it's even possible 
that they could find it easier. If you are out of a job  and if 
you have a supportive community that will provide you with 
transportation, babysitting, etc. ... you can vote. But if you are 
indifferent to the options, in fact, no amount of encouragement to 
vote will help.


There are voting systems that allow people to see the effect of their 
vote, even if they don't win, but mostly they are not on the table. 
Good voting systems don't just determine winners, though that's the 
primary purpose. They also collect and provide accurate information 
as to public preferences, guiding future elections and campaigns, and 
because collecting that information is cheap if it's part of an 
election process, and if the information collected is the kind that 
would allow predictions of future voting behavior, a great deal of 
general social benefit can be generated quite aside from the benefit 
of making decisions.


And this is another reason why we should collect preference strength 
data, because raw preference, simple preference order, does not allow 
us to make predictions with high confidence. An AB preference that 
is so small that tomorrow it might be BA is quite different from a 
strong preference! -- which takes an earthquake, so to speak, to 
reverse. Suppose a candidate loses an election with a very poor 
showing in first preference votes (which may be the only votes on a 
plurality ballot). But suppose this candidate is not only every 
voter's second choice, but the preference strength of the voters of 
someone else over this candidate is low. With support and better 
campaigning, that compromise candidate would be quite likely to win a 
rematch. And would, indeed, quite possibly, be a much better choice, 
uniting the community.


Hence if you asked me about the best voting method, I'd propose a 
Range ballot, of moderate resolution. Range ballots can be analysed 
as preferential, ranked ballots, with equal ranking allowed. If there 
is an explicit approval cutoff, they can be used to provide Yes/No 
information, to determine if a majority actually supports an outcome, 
which is highly useful and fits 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 16, 2010, at 12:05 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 11:22 AM 1/15/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:
(about a voting security expert)

you are in the rabid anti-IRV party.


Robert, your slip is showing.


what slip?  i don't have nuttin' under me kilt.


Experts in various fields tend to be strongly against IRV.  
Political activists who are working for IRV tend to see strong  
opposition as rabid. You want to see rabid opposition, you'll  
have to look elsewhere, though.


and FairVote.org will point to experts that strongly advocate IRV.   
big fat hairy deel.


whether it's here or on the Burlington blog or longer ago at the  
Fairvote site (that i have since gotten tired of), i have never  
appealed to authority in evaluating or advocating any method.


I'm thinking over the opposition material. It might look rabid to  
someone who isn't aware of the problems,


but i think i *am* aware of the salient problems.  but despite that,  
i support the goals that we had in adopting IRV.  i still don't  
support correcting IRV by reverting back to FPTP, given that is the  
choice presented (the reverted rules would include a delayed-runoff  
for less than 40%).  and voting security concerns have been  
persuasive.  even with IRV, with a reasonably small number of  
credible candidates (and assuming the worse case, that write-in is  
always the same person, without yet checking), there are a finite  
number of ranking permutations, and there can be a ballot for each.   
continued below...


On Jan 16, 2010, at 10:41 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 2:06 AM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:


On Jan 15, 2010, at 11:34 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:


On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:51 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

Imagine sending all your ballots nationwide to DC for manual  
counting
to check the outcome of a Presidential election. We'll simply  
let the

GW administration, for instance, count the results in his own IRV
election!


That's something of a non sequitur. Anyone with all the ballot files
(every state, for example, or anyone else) could do the count.


and, in fact, it can be decentralized to the extent it is now.   
each state
could have their central place, and in turn, each county, each  
precinct.
the entire tree could be a public record on the internet that has  
links to
child nodes or parent node.  with 3 credible candidates there are  
9 piles to
have to maintain.  each precinct sorts the ballots into one of 9  
piles and

counts it and puts the 9 numbers up in this public place on the web.
 everyone can check their own node to see that it isn't  
misreported.  i do

not see why, physically, it would be more vulnerable to attack by the
government in power that what is presently the case.  it's a  
factor of 9/2


a typo, i meant to say 9/3.  IRV has 9 piles, FPTP has 3.


more numbers to keep secure with that ranked ballot.


I was talking about IRV voting. Where do you get 9 piles from?


it's  3!/0! + 3!/2! = 6 + 3


(9 would be the number of Condorcet tallies for 3 candidates,


no, that would be 6.  for N candidates, i think there would be

N-1
SUM{ N!/n! } - N!/1!
n=0

  ... piles if only relative ranking is salient.

the second term of the summation (in the case of N=3, it's the number  
of permutations of ranking 2 candidates out of a pool of 3), counts a  
superfluous permutation because when only one candidate is unranked,  
it's equivalent to ranking him last.  but we have to account for the  
case where 2 or more candidates are unranked (and tied for last).



*not* the
number of ballot piles for either Condorcet - which does not require
ballot sorting to hand count - and *not* the number of ballot piles
for IRV voting.


doesn't matter if you don't worry about someone ranking their  
favorite candidate 2 and no one a 1.  there are a finite number  
of meaningfully different ranking permutations and you need only 1  
pile for each.  if N is 3, that number is 9.



If you want to make IRV precinct-summable for 3 candidates, it
requires 3*2 + 3*2 + 3 = 15 separate tallies.


the middle term of 3*2, you don't need.


To count IRV by sorting piles of ballots requires  far fewer piles
than 9 but also to do decentralized as you suggest would require
everyone in the entire country in all precincts sitting around waiting
for all the late-counted ballots to be ready and waiting for the total
results to be tabulated centrally somewhere so they could sort the
ballots for the next round - totally undoable practically.


if it makes a difference to the election outcome (like it's damn  
close), isn't sorting and counting late ballots going to be necessary  
anyway?



Of course the number of tallies to make IRV/STV precinct-summable
grows exponentially as the number of candidates grows and is equal to
more than the total number of voters who vote in each precinct most of
the time with a larger number of candidates.


it depends on who we expect 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 02:06 AM 1/16/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 15, 2010, at 11:34 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:

On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:51 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


Imagine sending all your ballots nationwide to DC for manual counting
to check the outcome of a Presidential election. We'll simply let the
GW administration, for instance, count the results in his own IRV
election!


That's something of a non sequitur. Anyone with all the ballot
files (every state, for example, or anyone else) could do the count.


and, in fact, it can be decentralized to the extent it is now.


It *can* be. Is it practical? Depends. Is it complicated? Yes. Is it 
vulnerable such that a small error somewhere compounds through the 
process, creating a necessity to recount elsewhere. Yes. Does this 
actually happen? Yes.


IRV creates many opportunities for close decisions, because each 
round involves finding the lowest vote-getter so that this candidate 
can be eliminated. This decision then affects the next round of 
counting, so if an error is found that flips one of these decision, 
*all subsequent counting* can be invalid.


This particular sensitivity is unique to sequential elimination, and 
it is why voting security experts are practically united in opposing 
IRV. Some of them are aware that there are better methods, even 
better in other ways, that don't have this problem.



  each
state could have their central place, and in turn, each county, each
precinct.   the entire tree could be a public record on the internet
that has links to child nodes or parent node.  with 3 credible
candidates there are 9 piles to have to maintain.


Nine? Three candidates, to be able to report all the votes for usage 
in central processing, there are 15 piles, even if we strike, at the 
outset, all write-ins, provisionally, or other minor candidates with no hope:


A
B
C
AB
AC
BA
BC
CA
CB
ABC
ACB
BAC
BCA
CAB
CBA
spoiled

and, in fact, for the one or two rank ballots above, most 
jurisdictions would need to report write-ins or minor candidates at 
least in first rank, before elimination. So we'd add: exhausted, 
which might be sorted as to first rank on the exhausted ballot.


Total 17, actually, with only three candidates. And if there are more 
than three, how do we know which ones to count? We have to sort them 
all. Note that three candidates is the simplest IRV election 
requiring rounds, unless there is a two-candidate election with a lot 
of write-in votes.


It's common to lump all write-ins together, and write-ins are 
normally only reported in first rank with IRV (because they are 
irrelevant after elimination), but ... should it happen that all the 
write-in votes collectively are enough to shift an elimination 
sequence that might affect the overall results, then they would have 
to go back and break down the write-ins. Notice that this adds 
another set of piles. Is this a three-rank ballot, or is it four?


If an error was made somewhere else, they have to back up and resort 
to the pile before considering that erroneous report. Do you have any 
idea how much work this is? Basically, how would you do it? You would 
pretty much have to go back to the beginning, and resort, though 
you'd use batch elimination of all previously eliminated candidates. 
Sorting a ballot with all these votes on them is a tedious process, 
compared to just counting all the votes, and it's easy to make mistakes.


You will, I'd guess, argue that the third rank votes are irrelevant, 
since we are going to ignore all other possibilities. But in an 
election method, we can't ignore them, we must be able to distinguish 
between ABW and ABC, where the write-in is W. It's true that 
ABW gets classified into AB after the initial elimination, but 
that counting must be done, creating, at least, a pile for Other as 
first preference. Or, say, Minor as first preference. And then, 
sometimes, if this single pile had enough votes in it in other 
jurisdictions, so that elimination can't be done in batch mode as 
mathematically irrelevant, you'd have to further sort...


It's a mess, Robert. They do it in Australia, by hand, so, sure, it 
can be done. They also, if I'm correct, don't allow write-ins. They 
do it centrally, so each voting district only maintains as many piles 
as candidates. For a long time, Australia didn't publish much of the 
election data, so we really don't know much about those elections. 
I'm not up on the latest



  each precinct
sorts the ballots into one of 9 piles and counts it and puts the 9
numbers up in this public place on the web.  everyone can check their
own node to see that it isn't misreported.  i do not see why,
physically, it would be more vulnerable to attack by the government
in power that what is presently the case.  it's a factor of 9/2 more
numbers to keep secure with that ranked ballot.


More. Simplifying assumptions have been made which make this look 
more practical.



each state, each little government would be 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 16, 2010, at 3:00 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 2:30 PM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:


I was talking about IRV voting. Where do you get 9 piles from?


it's  3!/0! + 3!/2! = 6 + 3


OK. If you prefer to write the formula that way, you're still  
incorrect.


It is 3!/0! + 3!/1! + 3!/2! = 15 unique vote combinations in IRV, but
that is also *not* the same as the number of piles you'll need to sort
into to count IRV, which is less. I haven't and don't plan to, figure
out that formula but do know that the answer is less than 9 for three
candidates when counting IRV manually, so I am still uncertain what
your 9 relates to.




(9 would be the number of Condorcet tallies for 3 candidates,


no, that would be 6.  for N candidates, i think there would be


Condorcet can always be counted by an n x n matrix where n is the
number of candidates. However you are correct that the diagonal has no
entries so 9 - 3 agrees with your six.

However, your fundamental formula below is incorrect for Condorcet and
for IRV and will not give correct answers for Condorcet except maybe
in the case of two and three candidates (your formula is also overly
complex and easily simplified but does not seem to apply to anything.
For instance, storing all the ballot choices for Condorcet can be done
for four candidates, as always, in a 4 x 4 matix with 4 diagonal
entries blank or used to store other useful items such as the number
of ballots cast, number of spoiled ballots, or whatever.

Again, I suggest you sit down and actually try to count some sample
ballots in either Condorcet or IRV.  That would help anyone to go from
the theory to practice.



   N-1
   SUM{ N!/n! } - N!/1!
   n=0

 ... piles if only relative ranking is salient.


Your formula would be correct for the number of tallies for IRV if you
delete the second expression that you subtract, but is not correct for
anything to do with Condorcet in general.



the second term of the summation (in the case of N=3, it's the  
number of

permutations of ranking 2 candidates out of a pool of 3), counts a
superfluous permutation because when only one candidate is  
unranked, it's
equivalent to ranking him last.  but we have to account for the  
case where 2

or more candidates are unranked (and tied for last).


Don't know what you're talking about.


consider Burlington 2009 with the inconsequential candidates Simpson  
and write-in eliminated and very real (but otherwise last)  
candidate Dan Smith eliminated.  that least Wright, Montroll, and  
Kiss.  with only those three left, these are the pile counts of the  
only salient permutations of marked ballots:


  1332  MKW
   767  MWK
   455  M
  2043  KMW
   371  KWM
   568  K
  1513  WMK
   495  WKM
  1289  W

now, Kathy, ask yourself why there are no piles marked just MK or  
MW or KM or KW or WM or WK?  (those are the 6 piles you want to  
enumerate in your 15.)




All your formulas are incorrect.


and, since you don't understand your opponent's argument, then your  
evaluation of it is authoritative.


sigh

--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 2:54 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
a...@lomaxdesign.com wrote:
 results. Generally, voting security people like to use audits that select a
 sample of votes and look for errors, then they use statistical analysis to
 estimate the overall error in result probability. That's not nearly as easy
 with IRV, because IRV is a chaotic method, sensitive to a single vote error
 that ripples into shifting many votes. With many places where that single
 vote error can occur.

 At least that's my understanding, I'd defer to Kathy on this!

Yes, IRV is virtually impossible (practically) to audit in a way that
the general public could understand. There are several ways to
manually audit IRV/STV as far as publicly reporting the tallies and
randomly selecting them:

1. report every rank choice ballot for every voter and make a humanly
readable mark on every ballot (preferrably after the voter casts or as
the voter casts the ballot to avoid vote-buying) that is also listed
alongside the ballot choices, and then randomly select ballots, or

2. publicly report all the tallies for each possible unique rank
choice vote for each precinct (a huge number larger than the number of
voters who vote in most precincts if there are many candidates
running), and then randomly sample from those, or

3. manually count 100% of the ballots

No one, to my knowledge, has tried to develop the mathematics for
sampling sufficiently to verify the accuracy of the election outcomes
to a desired high probability for IRV/STV and I wouldn't want to try.
It has got to be virtually impossible to figure out given how
difficult it has been just to develop the mathematics for the simple
plurality case.  Any method needs to be precinct-summable and possible
for the public to tally the results from whatever tallies are publicly
reported and IRV/STV does not meet that fundamental requirement for
the vast majority of the public who could not even comprehend how many
unique ballot combinations there are, let alone figure out how to
check the tallies from the publicly posted results.

Any other method than IRV/STV (any method that treats all voters'
votes equally) would be easier to figure out how to audit IMO,
although I've not tried to figure out how to audit any other methods
yet as far as the mathematics of sample sizes.

Abd ul your posts are always so informative.  Thank you.

-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-16 Thread Kathy Dopp
 Message: 2
 Date: Sat, 16 Jan 2010 15:14:23 -0500
 From: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com
 To: EM Methods election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

 Don't know what you're talking about.

 consider Burlington 2009 with the inconsequential candidates Simpson
 and write-in eliminated and very real (but otherwise last)
 candidate Dan Smith eliminated.  that least Wright, Montroll, and
 Kiss.  with only those three left, these are the pile counts of the
 only salient permutations of marked ballots:

   1332  MKW
    767  MWK
    455  M
   2043  KMW
    371  KWM
    568  K
   1513  WMK
    495  WKM
   1289  W

 now, Kathy, ask yourself why there are no piles marked just MK or
 MW or KM or KW or WM or WK?  (those are the 6 piles you want to
 enumerate in your 15.)

Robert, Your slip is showing again.

Exactly as I tried to point out to you, you were either disallowing
voters to rank only two candidates or to rank all three.  I see I was
correct and you are disallowing voters to rank only two candidates and
have, as Abd ul also pointed out to you, left 3 choose 2 or 6 possible
choices out of your list.

Unfortunately for your system of disallowing voters to rank only two
choices, US courts would rule that any such ballots where voters rank
only two choices as legal votes that must be counted, so you cannot
have a voting system in the US which disallows those choices.



 All your formulas are incorrect.

 and, since you don't understand your opponent's argument, then your
 evaluation of it is authoritative.

Robert I just proved you wrong, as did Abd ul earlier.  So please try
again if you think your other formula is correct, because
mathematically provably both your formulas are obviously incorrect to
any election methods expert on this list or any mathematician or
probabilist, not just to me.

Reality is a really nice place Robert. I invite you sincerely to join
us in the real world.

-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-16 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 16, 2010, at 3:41 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


Message: 2
Date: Sat, 16 Jan 2010 15:14:23 -0500
From: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com
To: EM Methods election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)


Don't know what you're talking about.


consider Burlington 2009 with the inconsequential candidates Simpson
and write-in eliminated and very real (but otherwise last)
candidate Dan Smith eliminated.  that least Wright, Montroll, and
Kiss.  with only those three left, these are the pile counts of the
only salient permutations of marked ballots:

  1332  MKW
   767  MWK
   455  M
  2043  KMW
   371  KWM
   568  K
  1513  WMK
   495  WKM
  1289  W

now, Kathy, ask yourself why there are no piles marked just MK or
MW or KM or KW or WM or WK?  (those are the 6 piles you want to
enumerate in your 15.)


Robert, Your slip is showing again.


no slip nor nuttin' else under me kilt.  want me to show you?


Exactly as I tried to point out to you, you were either disallowing
voters to rank only two candidates or to rank all three.


no, it has nothing at all to do with allowing or disallowing the  
voters to



  I see I was
correct and you are disallowing voters to rank only two candidates and
have, as Abd ul also pointed out to you, left 3 choose 2 or 6 possible
choices out of your list.


because all unmarked candidates are tied for last place, when there  
is only one unmarked candidate, there is *no* consequential  
difference between leaving that candidate unmarked or marking that  
candidate last.




Unfortunately for your system of disallowing voters to rank only two
choices, US courts would rule that any such ballots where voters rank
only two choices as legal votes that must be counted, so you cannot
have a voting system in the US which disallows those choices.





All your formulas are incorrect.


and, since you don't understand your opponent's argument, then your
evaluation of it is authoritative.


Robert I just proved you wrong, as did Abd ul earlier.  So please try
again if you think your other formula is correct, because
mathematically provably both your formulas are obviously incorrect to
any election methods expert on this list or any mathematician or
probabilist, not just to me.

Reality is a really nice place Robert. I invite you sincerely to join
us in the real world.



Kathy, come to the USENET newsgroup comp.dsp someday.  i'm quite used  
to analyzing and sometimes deconstructing arguments.


you haven't made a dent.

--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 4:17 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
a...@lomaxdesign.com wrote:
 It may depends on what office(s) are being elected. States are free,
 supposedly, to select their electors by any method they choose. STV is
 actually a decent method for that. This election would be state-wide. But it
 ain't gonna happen unless some negotations and arrangements are successful.
 There is a way to get from here to there, but it must address the problem
 that the majority party in each state will see that the all-or-nothing
 assignment of electors state by state helps it, and that this is somewhat
 balanced and somewhat fair when disparity, the loss of representation in the
 electoral college by all-or-nothing, balances out.

 So a Democratic state, for example, if it decides to generously divide up
 its electors fairly, will quite accurately perceive that it will be helping
 the Republican to win, and perhaps unfairly, if there is no reciprocation.
 There is a way around this through conditional implementations that only
 divide the electors when this actually will produce a fair result based on
 overall proportional representation in the electoral college. Otherwise it
 reverts to all-or-nothing, or something in between.

I love that idea Abd ul. It is a far better idea than trying to create
a nationwide popular vote compact IMO for exactly the reasoning you
mention below and the incredible legal finagling that could result
from a close popular vote in all 50 states given the completely
different election systems each state uses.  I wish the creators of
the popular vote compact (that IMO will never pass in enough states)
had taken that approach instead, which I would think also has a better
political chance of being endorsed in enough states.


 I strongly dislike basing the national result on direct popular vote, for
 two reasons, one of which is the election integrity problem.

 Ideally, the electoral college would return to its intended role, where
 electors could cast their votes *independently,* and were elected based on
 the trust of the public in them *personally*. If you want to only vote for a
 Green elector, fine. But let your elector cast his or her vote in the
 College according to what will produce the best result in the end, as seen
 by that person. Choose well.

 Part of the problem with the present system is that we are electing
 rubber-stamps, then we are surprised when rubber-stamp elections don't go
 well!


Today only NE and I think NB have allocated their electors
proportionally to the vote in their states.



-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

Kathy Dopp wrote:

On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 2:54 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
a...@lomaxdesign.com wrote:

results. Generally, voting security people like to use audits that select a
sample of votes and look for errors, then they use statistical analysis to
estimate the overall error in result probability. That's not nearly as easy
with IRV, because IRV is a chaotic method, sensitive to a single vote error
that ripples into shifting many votes. With many places where that single
vote error can occur.

At least that's my understanding, I'd defer to Kathy on this!


Yes, IRV is virtually impossible (practically) to audit in a way that
the general public could understand. There are several ways to
manually audit IRV/STV as far as publicly reporting the tallies and
randomly selecting them:

1. report every rank choice ballot for every voter and make a humanly
readable mark on every ballot (preferrably after the voter casts or as
the voter casts the ballot to avoid vote-buying) that is also listed
alongside the ballot choices, and then randomly select ballots, or

2. publicly report all the tallies for each possible unique rank
choice vote for each precinct (a huge number larger than the number of
voters who vote in most precincts if there are many candidates
running), and then randomly sample from those, or

3. manually count 100% of the ballots


Offtopic, perhaps, but would these problems hold for Condorcet as well? 
Both IRV and Condorcet methods are ranked-ballot ones, though I guess 
auditing Condorcet would be easier since it's precinct-summable. It 
doesn't appear to be as easy as Plurality, though, because you can't tie 
A beat B N times to what kind of votes the N voters submitted other 
than that they ranked A ahead of B.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-16 Thread Kristofer Munsterhjelm

robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 3:41 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:



Exactly as I tried to point out to you, you were either disallowing
voters to rank only two candidates or to rank all three.


no, it has nothing at all to do with allowing or disallowing the voters to


  I see I was
correct and you are disallowing voters to rank only two candidates and
have, as Abd ul also pointed out to you, left 3 choose 2 or 6 possible
choices out of your list.


because all unmarked candidates are tied for last place, when there is 
only one unmarked candidate, there is *no* consequential difference 
between leaving that candidate unmarked or marking that candidate last.


Is that true in IRV? Consider a vote of the sort:

A  B

where A and B are eliminated. Then this would be an empty vote, I think, 
and so be removed from the count, whereas if it had been


A  B  C

it would count as one point for C.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-16 Thread Kathy Dopp
Kristofer,

I don't know about Condorcet auditing because I haven't tried to
figure it out yet, but its mathematics seems to be much simpler than
IRV/STV since only n(n-1) counts are necessary to report for each
audit unit (precinct or whatever.) and I'm sure the fact that
Condorcet counts fit so nicely into an nxn matrix would probably help
the numeric algorithms.

I would need to figure out how what the upper margin error bounds for
all candidate pairs for one Condorcet audit unit (precinct or other
publicly reported) matrix are, given the reported vote counts and
number of ballots cast in each. Once that is done, I think figuring
out several methods would come simply.  It seems very do-able to me,
but it would take me who knows how many days or weeks or even months
of studying the problem to figure out exactly.  As soon as Condorcet
methods are adopted for a public federal, or perhaps even state-level
election, I would definitely not oppose implementation of the
Condorcet method with the minimum margin method of resolving cycles
and would be happy to try to develop the post-election auditing
mathematics for it.

Kathy

On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 4:55 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm
km-el...@broadpark.no wrote:
 Kathy Dopp wrote:

 On Sat, Jan 16, 2010 at 2:54 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax
 a...@lomaxdesign.com wrote:

 results. Generally, voting security people like to use audits that select
 a
 sample of votes and look for errors, then they use statistical analysis
 to
 estimate the overall error in result probability. That's not nearly as
 easy
 with IRV, because IRV is a chaotic method, sensitive to a single vote
 error
 that ripples into shifting many votes. With many places where that single
 vote error can occur.

 At least that's my understanding, I'd defer to Kathy on this!

 Yes, IRV is virtually impossible (practically) to audit in a way that
 the general public could understand. There are several ways to
 manually audit IRV/STV as far as publicly reporting the tallies and
 randomly selecting them:

 1. report every rank choice ballot for every voter and make a humanly
 readable mark on every ballot (preferrably after the voter casts or as
 the voter casts the ballot to avoid vote-buying) that is also listed
 alongside the ballot choices, and then randomly select ballots, or

 2. publicly report all the tallies for each possible unique rank
 choice vote for each precinct (a huge number larger than the number of
 voters who vote in most precincts if there are many candidates
 running), and then randomly sample from those, or

 3. manually count 100% of the ballots

 Offtopic, perhaps, but would these problems hold for Condorcet as well? Both
 IRV and Condorcet methods are ranked-ballot ones, though I guess auditing
 Condorcet would be easier since it's precinct-summable. It doesn't appear to
 be as easy as Plurality, though, because you can't tie A beat B N times to
 what kind of votes the N voters submitted other than that they ranked A
 ahead of B.




-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum) (Kathy Dopp)

2010-01-16 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 16, 2010, at 5:02 PM, Kristofer Munsterhjelm wrote:


robert bristow-johnson wrote:

On Jan 16, 2010, at 3:41 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:



Exactly as I tried to point out to you, you were either disallowing
voters to rank only two candidates or to rank all three.
no, it has nothing at all to do with allowing or disallowing the  
voters to

  I see I was
correct and you are disallowing voters to rank only two  
candidates and
have, as Abd ul also pointed out to you, left 3 choose 2 or 6  
possible

choices out of your list.
because all unmarked candidates are tied for last place, when  
there is only one unmarked candidate, there is *no* consequential  
difference between leaving that candidate unmarked or marking that  
candidate last.


Is that true in IRV? Consider a vote of the sort:

A  B

where A and B are eliminated. Then this would be an empty vote, I  
think, and so be removed from the count, whereas if it had been


A  B  C

it would count as one point for C.


now lemme see, if there are three candidates, how are two of them  
eliminated before the IRV final round?


and what counts in the IRV final round?  let's say that it's A  
eliminated before the IRV final round.  it doesn't matter if B is 1st  
or 2nd, if B ranked above (or is the only candidate left that's  
marked), it counts as a vote for B in the final round.  doesn't  
matter if C is marked below B or not marked at all.


think about it little bit, Kristofer, it *is* a useful fiction to  
leave the 2 bottom candidates (of 5) out of consideration (so one can  
get a grip of what happened in Burlington VT in 2009), but once  
you've done that (and you're considering only what happens between  
the remaining 3), the 9 numbers that are the only tallies you need to  
consider *any* counting scenario, IRV, Condorcet, Plurality of 1st  
choice, tallies for 1st or 2nd choice (some people in Burlington have  
suggested that as the number to use to determine the weakest  
candidate to eliminate in an IRV round), whatever, are:



  1332  MKW
   767  MWK
   455  M
  2043  KMW
   371  KWM
   568  K
  1513  WMK
   495  WKM
  1289  W


with exactly those three candidates in consideration, what  
consequential difference would it make in IRV (or any other rule of  
tabulation) if the [1332  MKW] pile was split into two piles;  
[MKW] and [MK] that totaled 1332?  those 9 numbers could certainly  
be determined in individual precincts and meaningfully summed at City  
Hall or the campaign headquarters of either candidate.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-16 Thread Kathy Dopp
 Date: Sat, 16 Jan 2010 18:40:09 -0500
 From: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com
 To: EM Methods election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

 unlike you, Kathy, i'm a lifelong student.  and, at 54, i've also

Hey Yet ANOTHER (count them) WRONG FANTASY about me that you've cooked
up inside your own head.

I have another lesson for you that you will probably ignore, like all
the rest. If you want to know the facts about someone else ASK THEM.
I.e. If ideas pop into your head about someone, your ideas may or may
*not* be correct, and the way to check the reality of your own
imagination is to ASK the other person about whom you continually
fabricate new fantasies or imaginary ideas about.

I am currently a Ph.D. student in political science after getting a
master's degree in mathematics.  I went back to college to get a Ph.D.
after getting tired of having Ph.D. professors replicate my work on
post-election auditing without citing my work and were incompetently
misleading people on how to do post-election audits.

 seen a few things and dealt with systems of significant complexity
 (and gotten paid for it).  one of my favorite contributions i like to
 make to the scholarly pile is to cut through unnecessary complexity
 and boil something down to the kernel of the issue.  for audio signal
 processing geeks, an example that's public-domain is http://
 www.musicdsp.org/files/EQ-Coefficients.pdf which has later become
 http://www.musicdsp.org/files/Audio-EQ-Cookbook.txt and has about
 6900 references on the web and 1000 in Google Scholar (none that i
 know of are negative references).  i dunno how many hits i get in
 Google Scholar, far less than a real academic.  i just checked and
 it's 9 more hits than you get Kathy.

Well I guess you are one-up in that regard then in the little pissing
contest you're having between yourself and your imaginary fabrications
about myself then. Congratulations.


 it's *you* that do not get it, Kathy.  neither quantitative nor
 qualitatively.

ha ha. Thanks for the laugh.


 and you're not very forthright, either.  you said earlier that you

Another hopelessly inaccurate fantasy.

Try to get this through your head. I do not live inside your head or
inside your imagination. I am living out here, in the real world which
is not restrained to your own imagination. If you want to expand your
own world, try learning about the world as others experience it rather
than trying to project your tiny illogical imagination where just
because people oppose IRV/STV you imagine that they are advocates of
FPTP and other hopelessly illogical ideas out in a spew of nonsense
and nastiness.

Try to get this through your head too.  It is *not* necessary to
belittle others, have a pissing contest with others, or put others
down in a derogatory fashion in order to build yourself up. We can all
rise together.

Try to get this through your head. I am **not** remotely like you are
and every time you add to the list of negative fabrications about me
that you've spewed, you reveal what is inside your imagination, not
one iota about me.

For instance, when I make an error, I almost immediately notice it and
correct it and immediately publicly admit it, just like I did today.

I can learn from anyone, even when the vast majority of what they say
is utter nonsense, as I did today from you.

I do not live inside your head or inside your imagination. I am very
very very different than you are, despite your repeatedly accusing me
of being like you are by projecting what is inside your head rather
than asking me.

 weren't attached to any partisan party (and given your definition,
 you meant like Dems and GOPs and Progs).  i've just been to http://
 kathydopp.com .  it says you're a Greenie.  you implied earlier that
 you had no party affiliation (and here i was only accusing you of
 being a rabid anti-IRV partisan) and that was not true.  your

TWO MORE FALSE claims about me (You never cease.)

1. I specifically said that I was affiliated with a party and asked
you to guess which one.

2. I am no longer affiliated with the Green party, but another party.
Sorry that page is out of date.

 credibility just took a nasty hit.  now we're gonna have to verify
 *every* claim you make that isn't ostensibly taken for granted.

Try to imagine this. I am **not** like you are.

I am no longer going to bother reading any more of your emails with
their plethora of fabrications and fantasies and delusional claims
asserting that illogical, obviously incorrect formulas are not so.  It
is a waste of my time.

I can only hope that you have learned something from this exchange,
despite your showing no evidence of that.

Perhaps you can sleep on it and figure it out while you sleep or in
ensuing days, and become wise enough someday to ask questions to
verify your imagination and actually consider and think reflectively
about what others are trying to help you understand.



Kathy Dopp

Town

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-16 Thread Jonathan Lundell
On Jan 16, 2010, at 5:17 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

 Try to get this through your head too.  It is *not* necessary to
 belittle others, have a pissing contest with others, or put others
 down in a derogatory fashion in order to build yourself up. 

Indeed.

 Try to get this through your head. I am **not** remotely like you are
 and every time you add to the list of negative fabrications about me
 that you've spewed, you reveal what is inside your imagination, not
 one iota about me.
 
 …
 
 I am no longer going to bother reading any more of your emails with
 their plethora of fabrications and fantasies and delusional claims
 asserting that illogical, obviously incorrect formulas are not so.  It
 is a waste of my time.

It's a hard lesson to learn, though.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-16 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 16, 2010, at 8:43 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:


On Jan 16, 2010, at 5:17 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


Try to get this through your head too.  It is *not* necessary to
belittle others, have a pissing contest with others, or put others
down in a derogatory fashion in order to build yourself up.


Indeed.


then let the facts speak for themselves, Jonathan.  let each person's  
words speak for themselves.


i stand by every factual and mathematical statement made.  Kathy (and  
those who stand with her, if any) are demonstrably wrong.


and it is Kathy who is projecting (and resorting the Rovian and  
Limbaughian tactic of accusing the other of exactly the recalcitrance  
they are guilty of, in an effort to divert attention from the fact  
they are doing it and to position themselves in a clean and  
elevated place to judge).


i'm comfortable with the facts, the maths, and my statements about  
them.  and my earlier judgements about character, interests,  
objectivity, and veracity have only been confirmed in front of all.



Try to get this through your head. I am **not** remotely like you are
and every time you add to the list of negative fabrications about me
that you've spewed, you reveal what is inside your imagination, not
one iota about me.


the facts speak louder than your words, Kathy.  and your previous  
words speak louder than your defenses do now.  you'll need to own them.



…

I am no longer going to bother reading any more of your emails with
their plethora of fabrications and fantasies and delusional claims
asserting that illogical, obviously incorrect formulas are not  
so.  It

is a waste of my time.


It's a hard lesson to learn, though.


care to be specific?

--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-15 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Fri, Jan 15, 2010 at 1:44 AM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:
 Kathy may make mistakes, but I'd be astonished to find her lying.

 she's pretty partisan (as am i), now i don't even remember what she said
 that i found so hard to believe.

Really!!??  Since I've never contributed or participated with *any*
campaign and my work has been completely nonpartisan, since you claim
*again* to be able to read my mind better than I can, what political
party do I belong to and am I so partisan with?

I did go to a particular political party convention that I was a
member of in order to give a presentation on the evidence consistent
with election tampering in the 2004 presidential contest.  Let's see
if your internal imagination can even guess which political party that
was??

Your deep confusion of your own imagination and reality is truly
astonishing Robert.  Many adults learn to recognize the difference
between imagination and reality and recognize that other individuals
know more about themselves and their own positions than the
imaginationer and do what is called reality checking by asking
questions to check whether what we imagine is real or not.  It is a
skill you obviously need to develop.

People who resort to making repeated (this is at least the 3rd or
forth time in just two days) false personal attacks Robert, do so
because they have nothing to back themselves up on the factual side of
an argument.  Your steady stream of false claims about me in your
recent emails show us much more about yourself than reveal anything
about me.

-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-15 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 15, 2010, at 9:47 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


On Fri, Jan 15, 2010 at 1:44 AM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:

Kathy may make mistakes, but I'd be astonished to find her lying.


she's pretty partisan (as am i), now i don't even remember what  
she said

that i found so hard to believe.


Really!!??  Since I've never contributed or participated with *any*
campaign and my work has been completely nonpartisan,


you're *very* partisan about the IRV vs. Plurality/Deleayed_runoff  
debate.  you are s anti-IRV that you have absolutely no  
recognition of the *well* *known* problems regarding Plurality in a  
multiparty, multi-candidate election.  you are so anti-IRV that you


partisan doesn't have to mean Dem vs GOP (or Prog vs. Libertarian  
whatever).  your unbending, not completely thoughtful (or at least  
thought out) positions (actually it position, singular) about this is  
precisely what identifies you as a bulldog.  a partisan bulldog.


that's what you are.



since you claim *again* to be able to read my mind better than I can,





what political party do I belong to and am I so partisan with?


see above.

you are in the rabid anti-IRV party.

it's someone else, but are tea-baggers partisan?  they're not Dem or  
GOP.  at least they claim not.




I did go to a particular political party convention


pf...



Your deep confusion of your own imagination and reality is truly
astonishing Robert.


yes it is.  whatever you say.

you complain about IRV.  i do too, you ignore it.

you complain about IRV, i offer plausible resolution to what we all  
recognize as problematic, but since it isn't the simplistic reversion  
to the old-fashioned FPTP that so heavily favors the two-party  
system, you ignore and infer that i am an IRV partisan (i think Terry  
wishes i *was*, but he has known for months that i am highly critical  
of it).  but i continue to recognize the reasons we ditched FPTP and  
adopted IRV in the first place (for just the mayoral race).  *those*  
are totally legit reasons and you have shown no acknowledgment of any  
of it.  you have made several factually incorrect statements, and  
when the content of those factually incorrect statements started  
being about me, my positions, and what i have said, i started to  
become incredulous.  NO ONE, reading this list or anything i said at  
FairVote (hell, i was arguing with Rob Richie himself) or in the  
local Burlington blogs, can credibly claim that i think that IRV is  
the solution.


but IRV is still better than FPTP for the multiparty, multi-candidate  
context.


but, if for a partisan bulldog, it's hard to listen.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-15 Thread Kathy Dopp
Oh. OK. I thought you were using the word partisan in the typical
sense of political party adherent which I am not.

OK. I agree that I am a strong adherent of voting rights so naturally
oppose IRV/STV as removing the rights of voters to participate in the
final decision-making process, removing the rights of voters to cast a
vote that positively affects the chances of candidates to win,
eviscerates the rights of voters to check the accuracy of the election
outcomes, etc.

Fine. I am a partisan bulldog for the rights of voters to have a fair
voting method, to be able to verify that the vote counting process is
accurate, and the rights of the voters to participate in the selection
of who represents them. However, I fight against any scheme that
violates those rights, esp. where others seem not to recognize the
threats, not just against the threat of IRV/STV which is only one such
threat.

So most people would not use the word partisan to characterize my
volunteer efforts, and not in the negative sense that you characterize
them, but OK, thanks for teaching me a new meaning for the word
partisan.

Kathy

On Fri, Jan 15, 2010 at 11:22 AM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:

 On Jan 15, 2010, at 9:47 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

 On Fri, Jan 15, 2010 at 1:44 AM, robert bristow-johnson
 r...@audioimagination.com wrote:

 Kathy may make mistakes, but I'd be astonished to find her lying.

 she's pretty partisan (as am i), now i don't even remember what she said
 that i found so hard to believe.

 Really!!??  Since I've never contributed or participated with *any*
 campaign and my work has been completely nonpartisan,

 you're *very* partisan about the IRV vs. Plurality/Deleayed_runoff debate.
  you are s anti-IRV that you have absolutely no recognition of the
 *well* *known* problems regarding Plurality in a multiparty, multi-candidate
 election.  you are so anti-IRV that you

 partisan doesn't have to mean Dem vs GOP (or Prog vs. Libertarian
 whatever).  your unbending, not completely thoughtful (or at least thought
 out) positions (actually it position, singular) about this is precisely what
 identifies you as a bulldog.  a partisan bulldog.

 that's what you are.


 since you claim *again* to be able to read my mind better than I can,



 what political party do I belong to and am I so partisan with?

 see above.

 you are in the rabid anti-IRV party.

 it's someone else, but are tea-baggers partisan?  they're not Dem or GOP.
  at least they claim not.


 I did go to a particular political party convention

 pf...


 Your deep confusion of your own imagination and reality is truly
 astonishing Robert.

 yes it is.  whatever you say.

 you complain about IRV.  i do too, you ignore it.

 you complain about IRV, i offer plausible resolution to what we all
 recognize as problematic, but since it isn't the simplistic reversion to the
 old-fashioned FPTP that so heavily favors the two-party system, you ignore
 and infer that i am an IRV partisan (i think Terry wishes i *was*, but he
 has known for months that i am highly critical of it).  but i continue to
 recognize the reasons we ditched FPTP and adopted IRV in the first place
 (for just the mayoral race).  *those* are totally legit reasons and you have
 shown no acknowledgment of any of it.  you have made several factually
 incorrect statements, and when the content of those factually incorrect
 statements started being about me, my positions, and what i have said, i
 started to become incredulous.  NO ONE, reading this list or anything i said
 at FairVote (hell, i was arguing with Rob Richie himself) or in the local
 Burlington blogs, can credibly claim that i think that IRV is the solution.

 but IRV is still better than FPTP for the multiparty, multi-candidate
 context.

 but, if for a partisan bulldog, it's hard to listen.


 --

 r b-j                  ...@audioimagination.com

 Imagination is more important than knowledge.








-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-15 Thread Abd ul-Rahman Lomax

At 10:51 PM 1/14/2010, Jonathan Lundell wrote:

On Jan 14, 2010, at 7:17 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:

 Again, as I mentioned, the Condorcet Criterion looks good, it's 
intuitively satisfying. Unfortunately, it depends on pure rank 
order, neglecting preference strength.


Just for the record: for many of us that's an advantage.


Sure. Those who don't trust voters and who imagine that Range voting 
is susceptible to damage from Strategic Voting (which is a misnomer 
because the term originally referred to votes which reversed 
preference order, and Range never encourages that, period), are going 
to think that allowing voters to present a maximally accurate 
preference profile is harmful.


With no evidence that it *actually* is. All evidence I've seen that 
claims to show it has been based on preposterous assumptions. Such as 
the assumption that voters who voted 100% A and 99% B are somehow 
going to be screwed by a minority of voters who voted 0% and 100% B.


Pure ranked methods can't distinguish at all between a trivial or 
barely perceptible preference and a deep and important one. So the 
fix these people propose is: don't allow voters to express their true feelings!


However, rank order methods which allow equal ranking do provide a 
partial fix, but then the same people will scream that voters are 
again being STRATEGIC if, on the one hand, they use equal preference 
if they really have a preference, or, on the other, they don't 
equal rank if they really approve both candidates equally but don't 
equal rank them. Can't win with these people.


It was noticed long ago that there was no single sincere Approval 
vote, but rather a class of such votes, being all voting patterns 
that do not violate rank-order by reversing sincere rank. This is how 
the major disagreement arose between whether or not Approval was 
vulnerable to strategic voting, with Brams originally claiming that 
it was strategy-free and then others arguing that it was highly 
vulnerable, which is assumed to be a bad thing. Approval strategy 
involves the voters estimating the need for compromise, and according 
to that estimation, they lower their approval cutoff. In other words, 
it's a compromise, and all compromises are strategic in the sense 
that if the voter knew nothing about the other voters and had any 
significant preference at all, the voter would simply vote the 
preference. But they are not strategic in that the vote, as writ, 
indicates a sincere division of the candidates into two groups: 
approved and not-approved. Or not approved-yet.


In approval voting as a repeated ballot method (an excellent 
application), voters in the first round would bullet vote, or only 
add approvals that were so close to the first preference that the 
voter prefers to get it over with than start out with a bullet vote.


In other words, approval voting in rounds results in a sliding down 
of approval cutoff (plus the possible introduction of new candidates 
in some repeated balloting methods, or the simplifying process of 
candidate withdrawals), which makes repeated ballot approval 
incorporate sincere personal utility estimates.


The point I was making was that there exist circumstances where, if 
we know the true situation with the voters, forget voting methods 
entirely!, we will not choose the Condorcet winner, and, this is very 
important:


Neither will the voters choose that, once they know. In some of the 
examples proposed, we can safely assume that the voters will 
unanimously approve the choice of other than what the initial 
majority preference was. All it takes is a weak majority preference 
and a strong minority one, within certain normal limits.


This is a conclusive proof, if you look at those situations, that the 
Condorcet winner can not only be suboptimal, it can be highly so. But 
this has nothing to do with core support, which is a bogus 
criterion made up by FairVote to try to find some kind of silver 
lining in the massive cloud that surrounds IRV. Unfortunately, the 
silver lining doesn't exist for IRV outside of a certain situation: 
2-party system, no-hope third parties who can only spoil elections at 
most, and there IRV protects the major parties and largely screws the 
minor ones in the long term. Did you ever wonder why Australia ended 
up using IRV? Try looking at the history!


But, of course, FairVote has convinced quite a few minor party 
leaders that it will be Good For Them because it allows their 
members to express their sincere preference. But that good is 
accomplished through polls, in fact, and is better handled by Fusion 
Voting anyway, which gives actual clout to a third party, which 
retains the ability to spoil elections if it decides that's better 
than tolerating the major party snubbing them.


Third party strength is also better measured by donations to the 
party, which might be better spent in other ways than useless 
campaigning. However, that campaigning expense isn't wasted 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-15 Thread Dave Ketchum

On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:46 PM, Juho wrote:

On Jan 14, 2010, at 2:13 AM, Dave Ketchum wrote:

On Jan 13, 2010, at 4:49 AM, Juho wrote:

On Jan 13, 2010, at 9:14 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

it still is a curiosity to me how, historically, some leaders and  
proponents of election reform thunked up the idea to have a  
ranked-order ballot and then took that good idea and married it  
to the IRV protocol.  with the 200 year old Condorcet idea in  
existence, why would they do that?


1) The basic idea of IRV is in some sense natural. It is like a  
street fight. The weakest players are regularly kicked out and  
they must give up. I'm not saying that this would lead to good  
results but at least this game is understandable to most people.  
Condorcet on the other hand is more like a mathematical equation,  
and the details of the most complex Condorcet variants may be too  
much for most voters. Here I'm not saying that each voter (and not  
even each legislator) should understand all the details of their  
voting system. The basic Condorcet winner rule is however a simple  
enough principle to be explained to all. But it may be that IRV is  
easier to market (to the legislators and voters) from this point  
of view.


When there is a CW in Condorcet, the CW has won in comparison with  
each other candidate.  While a few may like X or Z enough better to  
have given such top ranking, the fact that all the voters together  
prefer the CW over each other should count, and does with Condorcet.


Else there is a cycle in Condorcet.  Perhaps the following Minimum  
Margins Method Condorcet variant should be used to establish  
Condorcet's preferability over other methods.  Then let other  
variants compete with this one before finally deciding which to use.


Minimum Margins Method:  Consider the cycle, such as ABCA, and  
the margins that create it, such as 60A30B, 40B20C, 21C20A.   
Delete the weakest margins as many times as needed to destroy the  
cycle - in this case A becoming the CW (note that if one CA voter  
had voted AC in  this election, A would have become CW with no  
cycle).


When I see this kind of scenarios I'm always tempted to ask the  
question if it is necessary to limit the scope to the top cycle  
members or if one can allow also the others win (when the cyclic  
opinions in the top cycle are strong). I find also that approach to  
be a working solution for many election types (although many have  
indicated that they disagree with this).


Note that this method breaks the cycle at the point where the smallest  
number of ballots being voted differently would have broken the cycle.


Note that weaker candidates are unlikely to get enough votes to be  
part of a cycle - being weak they get few high rank votes.


2) IRV is easier to count manually. Condorcet gets quite tedious  
to count manually when the number of candidates and voters goes  
up. One can use some tricks and shortcuts to speed up manual  
Condorcet counting but IRV probably still beats it from this point  
of view. Manual counting was the only way to count for a long  
time. Nowadays we have computers and Condorcet tabulation should  
thus be no problem at all (at least in places where computers are  
available). But this is one reason why IRV has taken an early lead.


When an election district has only one polling place, life is simple.

When the district is a state or city, life is more complex for each  
method.
   With IRV you first want top ranks from all the ballots in the  
district.  If there is no majority winner all the ballots for the  
worst loser must be scanned for all the polling places for whom  
those voters ranked next.  Repeat until winner gets decided.
   With Condorcet each ballot gets scanned one time and its content  
added into an N*N array, with such arrays summed for the whole  
district.


Maybe scanning and other ballot checking can be done only once.  
After that IRV requires either central counting or central control  
of the distributed counting process.


How the counters go about their job is hard to define.  My point was  
that after a losing candidate is identified, ballots ranking that  
candidate high are the ones whose content must be findable in IRV -  
matters not if you must go back to the actual ballot, or someplace  
else which can provide THAT information.


3) Large parties are typically in a key role when electoral  
reforms are made. Election method experts within those parties may  
well have found out that IRV tends to favour large parties. In  
addition to trying to improve the society the best way they can,  
political parties and people within them also tend to think that  
they are the ones who are right and therefore the society would  
benefit of just them being in power and getting more votes and  
more seats. The parties and their representatives may also have  
other more selfish drivers behind their interest to grab as large  
share of the power as possible 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-15 Thread Kathy Dopp
 Message: 3
 Date: Fri, 15 Jan 2010 22:05:58 -0500
 From: Dave Ketchum da...@clarityconnect.com
 To: Juho juho4...@yahoo.co.uk

 On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:46 PM, Juho wrote:
 On Jan 14, 2010, at 2:13 AM, Dave Ketchum wrote:
 On Jan 13, 2010, at 4:49 AM, Juho wrote:
 On Jan 13, 2010, at 9:14 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

 it still is a curiosity to me how, historically, some leaders and
 proponents of election reform thunked up the idea to have a
 ranked-order ballot and then took that good idea and married it
 to the IRV protocol.  with the 200 year old Condorcet idea in
 existence, why would they do that?

 1) The basic idea of IRV is in some sense natural. It is like a
 street fight. The weakest players are regularly kicked out and
 they must give up. I'm not saying that this would lead to good
 results but at least this game is understandable to most people.
 Condorcet on the other hand is more like a mathematical equation,

Yet Condorcet is simple to count and precinct-summable, monotonic, and
treats all voters' votes equally, unlike IRV/STV which is virtually
impossible to manually count, requires a mind-boggling number of piles
and subpiles to count it and requires that all late-counted ballots
are ready to count centrally, or the entire long tedious process has
to be restarted.

 and the details of the most complex Condorcet variants may be too
 much for most voters. Here I'm not saying that each voter (and not
 even each legislator) should understand all the details of their
 voting system. The basic Condorcet winner rule is however a simple
 enough principle to be explained to all. But it may be that IRV is
 easier to market (to the legislators and voters) from this point
 of view.

The organization promoting IRV/STV is very well-funded and invests a
lot of capital into highly misleading local advertising campaigns in
order to promote its adoption.  I could send this list some
information on that if anyone is interested.  I don't think that any
group promoting a fair, equitable, auditable alternative method like
Condorcet or others has put forth such a well-funded campaign have
they?


 When there is a CW in Condorcet, the CW has won in comparison with
 each other candidate.  While a few may like X or Z enough better to
 have given such top ranking, the fact that all the voters together
 prefer the CW over each other should count, and does with Condorcet.

 Else there is a cycle in Condorcet.  Perhaps the following Minimum
 Margins Method Condorcet variant should be used to establish
 Condorcet's preferability over other methods.  Then let other
 variants compete with this one before finally deciding which to use.

 Minimum Margins Method:  Consider the cycle, such as ABCA, and
 the margins that create it, such as 60A30B, 40B20C, 21C20A.
 Delete the weakest margins as many times as needed to destroy the
 cycle - in this case A becoming the CW (note that if one CA voter
 had voted AC in  this election, A would have become CW with no
 cycle).

Great idea. Is this Dave Ketchum speaking above?  Very simple and
logically coherent plan.  Thanks for sharing.  Could it be possible
that this plan would ever not work? (I.e. same margins?)


 When I see this kind of scenarios I'm always tempted to ask the
 question if it is necessary to limit the scope to the top cycle
 members or if one can allow also the others win (when the cyclic
 opinions in the top cycle are strong). I find also that approach to
 be a working solution for many election types (although many have
 indicated that they disagree with this).

 Note that this method breaks the cycle at the point where the smallest
 number of ballots being voted differently would have broken the cycle.

 Note that weaker candidates are unlikely to get enough votes to be
 part of a cycle - being weak they get few high rank votes.

Yes, one could certainly say that this allows the top cycle to prevail
by breaking the weakest link where weakest is defined as the smallest
margin in this case.  This minimum margins method is so logically
correct and fair.


 2) IRV is easier to count manually. Condorcet gets quite tedious

Whomever said this obviously hasn't ever counted any IRV or STV
elections manually in a contest with a substantial number of
candidates and voters.  Condorcet is orders of magnitude simpler to
count than is IRV because there can never be more than n x n tallies
to tally in each precinct and those tallies are precinct-summable,
whereas IRV requires tallying

n*(n-1)*(n-2) + n(n-1) +n tallies for each precinct even if the voter
is only allowed to rank three choices - a huge number of tallies as
the number of candidates grows large and a much larger amount as the
number of allowed rankings goes up - for each precinct, at least if
the method is made precinct-summable rather than using a huge number
of sorting piles which I haven't yet derived the formulas for and have
no plans to do so.

The reason it takes cities over a month to manually count 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-15 Thread Jonathan Lundell
On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:51 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

 Imagine sending all your ballots nationwide to DC for manual counting
 to check the outcome of a Presidential election. We'll simply let the
 GW administration, for instance, count the results in his own IRV
 election!

That's something of a non sequitur. Anyone with all the ballot files (every 
state, for example, or anyone else) could do the count.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (Dave Ketchum)

2010-01-15 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 15, 2010, at 11:34 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:


On Jan 15, 2010, at 7:51 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


Imagine sending all your ballots nationwide to DC for manual counting
to check the outcome of a Presidential election. We'll simply let the
GW administration, for instance, count the results in his own IRV
election!


That's something of a non sequitur. Anyone with all the ballot  
files (every state, for example, or anyone else) could do the count.


and, in fact, it can be decentralized to the extent it is now.  each  
state could have their central place, and in turn, each county, each  
precinct.   the entire tree could be a public record on the internet  
that has links to child nodes or parent node.  with 3 credible  
candidates there are 9 piles to have to maintain.  each precinct  
sorts the ballots into one of 9 piles and counts it and puts the 9  
numbers up in this public place on the web.  everyone can check their  
own node to see that it isn't misreported.  i do not see why,  
physically, it would be more vulnerable to attack by the government  
in power that what is presently the case.  it's a factor of 9/2 more  
numbers to keep secure with that ranked ballot.


each state, each little government would be responsible to confirm  
their precinct totals on the map and everybody gets to look at it.   
what's particularly insecure about that?


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Kathy Dopp
 Date: Wed, 13 Jan 2010 22:24:53 -0500
 From: Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a...@lomaxdesign.com
 To: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com,  EM Methods
        election-methods@lists.electorama.com

 At 02:14 AM 1/13/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


IRV/STV is fundamentally unfair because a large group of persons whose
first choice loses, never has their 2nd choice counted,

only if they don't mark their 2nd choice.

IRV promoters should do due diligence to understand how IRV works.
There are several scenarios where voters' marked 2nd choices are never
counted, even when their first choice loses, and this is what makes
IRV/STV such a fundamentally unfair system that tends to elect extreme
right or left candidates while eliminating the majority favored
candidates.

Cases when voters' 2nd choices are never counted include:

1. 2nd and later choices eliminated prior to 1st choice, and the most
important case

2. the very large group of voters whose 1st choice makes it to the
final counting round and then loses

The above will *always* happen in all IRV/STV elections. In
particular, #1 above occurs anytime that there are a number of
candidates that is greater by one (1) than the number of ballot
positions.

This fundamental inequity is what causes nonmonotonicity, elimination
of majority-favorite candidates, and the fact that commonly IRV/STV
does not find majority winners because so many voters' ballots are
exhausted prior to the final counting round, thus involuntarily
excluding a large number of voters from participating in making the
final decision as to who is elected.

I truly cannot imagine a worse voting method than IRV/STV which fails
more of Arrow's fairness criteria than plurality voting does.

Kathy



 No. Damn it, I wish people would make more effort to understand the
 scope of the problem! Robert, I expect you to say Ooops!

 I vote for A and for B as a second choice. In the first round of IRV
 counting, B is eliminated. My second choice is never counted, because
 my first choice, A, was still standing when B was eliminated.

 That's the effect of the Later-No-Harm compliance of IRV, and a
 simple example of the destruction LNH wreaks. It doesn't matter if B
 is the Condorcet winner by a landslide, if B is the second choice of
 every voter, with vastly higher satisfaction overall if elected, that
 first preference vote, to the FairVote activists and anyone who
 drinks their Kool-Aid, is sacrosanct.

 Even if a first preference vote is with very low or even absent
 preference strength. Try to equal rank in first preference, or any
 preference, and you know what the IRV counting rules will do, don't
 you. Tell me why the system throws that information out? It has an
 obvious meaning! It means that the voter is claiming to be equally
 satisfied by the election of either candidate!

 IRV with equal ranking allowed would be a much better method;
 basically it would be Approval voting in first round, or later
 rounds. But Bucklin is more straightforward and far easier to
 understand. The elimination algorithm of IRV is just plain weird and
 chaotic, take a look at those Yee diagrams. It looks simple. It is
 far from simple.

   otherwise, that's
certainly not true.

 Well, Robert has a golden opportunity now. He can recognize that he
 can be certain about a thing and be dead wrong. That is
 extraordinarily valuable! Take the opportunity, Robert, I promise you
 that the pain, if there is even any, will be transient, and, in the
 long run, you'll even be happy you made the mistake.

   (unfair is subjective, but the latter half is
untrue for voters who mark a 2nd choice with 3 credible candidates.
or do you mean that if they vote for the 2 biggest losers, their 3rd
or 4th choice that *does* count in the final round isn't their 2nd
choice so it's unfair?)  IRV is screwed up, but you still have made
no case that the weird pathologies of IRV are worse than the widely
known pathologies of plurality in a multi-party or multi-candidate
context.

 The original comment was quite correct (but, yes, unfair is
 subjective unless qualified, but, indeed, it could be qualified with
 reasonable fairness criteria). Suppose there are three credible
 candidates, we'll call them A, B, and C. No, the example given isn't
 what's being talked about. The statement is literally true. Except by
 op-scan ballot images that show those second choice votes, they are
 literally never counted. With hand counting, they would never be
 counted. I think you'd better review how IRV works! When a candidate
 is eliminated, votes for that candidate are not counted from that
 point on, and if they haven't been counted before that, they are
 never counted. So with IRV, it is quite clearly true that it's
 possible that every single voter votes for a candidate, casts a vote
 for a candidate, and the candidate is not elected. You may think
 that's fair, but I don't. When that happens, not every vote was
 counted and my slogan is

 Count 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 14, 2010, at 11:03 AM, Kathy Dopp wrote:


Date: Wed, 13 Jan 2010 22:24:53 -0500
From: Abd ul-Rahman Lomax a...@lomaxdesign.com
To: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com,  EM Methods
   election-methods@lists.electorama.com

At 02:14 AM 1/13/2010, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


IRV/STV is fundamentally unfair because a large group of persons  
whose

first choice loses, never has their 2nd choice counted,


only if they don't mark their 2nd choice.


IRV promoters should do due diligence to understand how IRV works.


listen, Kathy, in case you haven't noticed, i've been pretty critical  
of IRV also (in case you're labeling me as an IRV promoter).  and i  
understand exactly how IRV (as it had been enacted in Burlington)  
works.  your criticism notwithstanding.



There are several scenarios where voters' marked 2nd choices are never
counted, even when their first choice loses,


if their 1st choice loses at some time before the final round, their  
2nd choice is promoted to 1st choice and is not removed until after  
*it* loses.  but for it to lose, it is counted and, by the dumb IRV  
rules, is considered to come up short.


do you mean their 2nd choice is not counted because their first  
choice loses in the final round?  that goes without saying, but  
that's the dumb IRV rules.  that is an *arbitrary* threshold imposed  
upon IRV, that 1st choices count and *anything* below the 1st choice  
makes *no* difference until it gets bumped off and every other choice  
gets bumped up.



and this is what makes
IRV/STV such a fundamentally unfair system that tends to elect extreme
right or left candidates while eliminating the majority favored
candidates.


it tends to elect the candidate from the larger subgroup (in  
Burlington, Prog vs. Dem) of the larger group (left vs. right).  if  
the fringes were smaller than the center, it would elect the center  
candidate.  but, at least if you use the mayoral vote as a measure,  
in Burlington Vermont, there are more Progs than Dems.


but the elimination criterion is faulty in IRV, I KNOW THAT (next  
time you call me an IRV proponent, i am going to remind you that  
you don't read).  considering the big 3 (after write-in, Simpson,  
and Smith are out of the picture), IRV simple-mindedly identified  
Montroll as the biggest loser and promoted the Wright or Kiss votes  
on the Montroll 1st ballots.  there are more Dems in Burlington that  
align with Progs than GOPs.


but what would have happened if the rules were different?  what would  
have happened if the tabulation algorithm considered eliminating (for  
the time being) either Wright or Kiss?  we know what would happen.


but then, one might ask, by what reasonable measure would we  
eliminate Wright or Kiss over Montroll?  i heard one guy suggest that  
they should count *both* 1st and 2nd choices for evaluating which  
candidate is the weakest and eliminated.  but that's just another  
made-up threshold that someone pulled out of their butt.  in a sense,  
Condorcet considers *every* case of elimination, and draws an  
inference about who the winner is.  no arbitrary thresholds.




Cases when voters' 2nd choices are never counted include:

1. 2nd and later choices eliminated prior to 1st choice, and the most
important case


if their 1st choice survives and counts, how is it that Plurality  
supporters can complain?  with Plurality, the same vote survives to  
count and their 2nd-choices wouldn't have even been recorded.



2. the very large group of voters whose 1st choice makes it to the
final counting round and then loses


so their 1st choice beats their 2nd choice.  why would they complain  
about that?


or, are you complaining that their 1st choice lost to someone who was  
worse than their 2nd choice?  we know about that.  sometimes it's a  
pathology and that pathology actually happened in Burlington in  
2009.  in case you didn't notice, i brought that up several times.   
the result is that the GOP Prog-haters in Burlington are gonna have  
to be considering strategic voting (compromising) in 2012, assuming  
IRV survives.



The above will *always* happen in all IRV/STV elections. In
particular, #1 above occurs anytime that there are a number of
candidates that is greater by one (1) than the number of ballot
positions.


that wasn't the case in Burlington with 5 candidates, one of which  
was completely inconsequential and did not campaign at all.



This fundamental inequity is what causes nonmonotonicity,


Yawn.  non-monotonicity for the non-Condorcet candidate.  that guy  
should lose anyway.



elimination
of majority-favorite candidates, and the fact that commonly IRV/STV
does not find majority winners because so many voters' ballots are
exhausted prior to the final counting round, thus involuntarily
excluding a large number of voters from participating in making the
final decision as to who is elected.


but Kathy, the solution to that is Condorcet and you 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 13, 2010, at 8:26 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:


On Jan 13, 2010, at 5:02 PM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:


On Jan 13, 2010, at 7:57 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:


This seems to me to be a claim that is at best not self-evident  
(in the sense that Pareto or anti-dictatorship, say, are). While  
I'm not a fan of cardinal-utility voting systems, it seems  
entirely possible to make a utility argument or rationale against  
the *necessity* of electing the CW in all cases.


That is, as a thought experiment, if we could somehow divine a  
workable electorate-wide utility function, it's at least arguable  
that the utility winner would legitimately trump the Condorcet  
winner, if different, while you couldn't make a similar argument  
wrt Pareto or dictatorship.


how would you define that utility function metric in a  
democracy?  would the candidates arm-wrestle?  take a written  
exam? flip a coin?  what, other than majority preference of the  
electorate, can be such a metric in a democracy?


I don't think you can, and that's a big problem for Range, it seem  
to me.


But we're talking about utility for the voter, not arm-strength of  
the candidates.



I guess I didn't understand that the utility function was for the  
individual voter.  Yes, that *is* Range voting.  And if the value is  
restricted to binary, it's Approval voting.  Especially if you add up  
the values of a candidate for all voters (maybe we should add their  
square-roots, I dunno).


we have a choice of candidates.  only one candidate can be elected  
(single winner).  the best candidate means that this candidate is  
better than any other candidate.  if we define better than the  
other candidate as preferred by more voters than prefer the other  
candidate (it's a dichotomy, the alternative is to give it to the  
*less* preferred candidate, unless we make them arm wrestle, or take  
a written exam or something other criterion without votes), then the  
Condorcet candidate is better than every other candidate.


I guess I still haven't heard a good justification for why the  
Condorcet winner, if one exists, should *ever* be rejected as the  
elected winner.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Jonathan Lundell
On Jan 14, 2010, at 9:34 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

 do you mean their 2nd choice is not counted because their first choice loses 
 in the final round?  that goes without saying, but that's the dumb IRV rules. 
  that is an *arbitrary* threshold imposed upon IRV, that 1st choices count 
 and *anything* below the 1st choice makes *no* difference until it gets 
 bumped off and every other choice gets bumped up.
 …
 but then, one might ask, by what reasonable measure would we eliminate Wright 
 or Kiss over Montroll?  i heard one guy suggest that they should count *both* 
 1st and 2nd choices for evaluating which candidate is the weakest and 
 eliminated.  but that's just another made-up threshold that someone pulled 
 out of their butt. 

Looking only at the current top rank is necessary to preserve later-no-harm. 
You may not like it, but it's not arbitrary.


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 13, 2010, at 3:15 PM, Abd ul-Rahman Lomax wrote:


At 09:30 AM 1/13/2010, Terry Bouricius wrote:




It has been argued that IRV tends to reduce negative campaigning,  
or makes
campaigns overly bland (depending on your stance), because in  
addition to
seeking first choices, candidates want to reach out to the  
supporters of

other candidates.


It's been argued, for sure, but it's never been shown.


and the IRV detractors make the same claim, but tout it as a bad  
thing.  they want *real* campaigns, complete with sparks or mud or  
fecal matter flying in all directions.  not any of this namby-pamby  
love-fest bullshit.  :-)


hell, if the Tea-Baggers have their way, we'll be bringing our guns  
to the debates.



However, with Condorcet rules, it is possible for a
candidate to win in a crowded field while receiving no first  
choices at

all.


Horrors! The candidate must really be bad, not even his or her  
mother votes for him, nor, indeed, does the candidate vote for  
himself or herself. I love these objections to voting methods that  
are based on utterly preposterous scenarios and expected knee-jerk  
responses to them.


i've never considered that a persuasive argument at all for IRV  
against Condorcet.  a few months ago when i was taking on Rob Richie  
about it at FairVote.org, i was calling that the winner as warm  
bucket of spit argument.  Andy Montroll *did* come in third, in  
terms of 1st-choice votes in 2009 (if he came in any higher, he would  
win IRV).  but his base was just fine and we don't look at it that  
way in a traditional two-person race (then why should we for multi- 
candidate races?).  a candidate's hard-core base is something we  
think about in terms of campaign strategy, getting out the vote,  
etc.  but when it comes to the election, the votes for that candidate  
from the hard-core base count *no* *more* than the votes for that  
candidate from voters who just happen to like that candidate better  
than the opponent.  why should it be any different for IRV/Condorcet?



However, there is a legitimate point here, let's look at it.


There haven't been any real-world high-stakes elections to know for
certain what effect this might have, but it would seem reasonable to
expect candidates to avoid taking stands on controversial issues.


i don't agree with that.  a statement put forth with absolutely no  
empirical data backing it up.


No, actually, at least not more than happens at present, where  
candidates try to avoid opposing the positions of large blocks of  
the public, and will attempt to present themselves differently to  
different interest groups, whenever they think they can get away  
with it.


The problem is that if you make yourself as bland as possible, you  
will lose your support base, those highly motivated to turn out and  
vote for you, work for your election as a volunteer, contribute  
funds to help you gain name recognition, etc. Fatal under most  
realistic voting systems, including Range, IRV, etc.


i agree with that.

Candidates would have an incentive to campaign just using a vacant  
theme

of I promise to listen to YOU.


This is supposed to be new and only hypothetical? Sorry, Terry, I  
vote against candidates like that, and I think I'm not alone. I'll  
vote for a candidate whom I *actually trust* to listen to the  
constiuents, but not one who will not disclose his or her own  
position, because I can't trust the latter to vote intelligently  
and honestly. I don't want a rubber stamp in a legislature or  
office, I want someone who will not only listen, but make  
reasonably decent decisions as well, *after* having listened.  
Someone who won't tell me what they think, who avoids revealing  
personal positions, that's a very big negative for me.


Unfortunately, the present systems encourage exactly this.

IRV seems to strike a reasonable balance between appealing for a  
strong
core of supporters (the only requirement  in a plurality election  
with
many candidates) and also developing broad appeal as an alternate  
choice.


The problem is that a political expedient is mistaken for a  
desirable quality. And it's just plain bullshit. IRV favors  
extremists, not centrists. And not *real* centrists. I'm afraid  
that Terry is reasoning backwards. He's long worked for IRV, so he  
is making up reasons why it's a good method, a reasonable  
balance, even though anyone who has studied voting systems without  
this kind of activist bias knows that IRV performs far from  
reasonably.


and for me, Terry, it just doesn't trump the principles:

1. If a majority (not just a mere plurality) of voters agree that  
candidate A is

better than candidate B, then candidate B should not be elected.
2. The relative merit of candidates A and B is not affected by the  
presence of a
third candidate C. If a majority (not just a mere plurality) of  
voters agree that
candidate A is better than B, whether candidate C enters the race or  

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Thu, Jan 14, 2010 at 12:34 PM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:



I'm glad to hear you don't support IRV/STV methods.

 There are several scenarios where voters' marked 2nd choices are never
 counted, even when their first choice loses,

 if their 1st choice loses at some time before the final round, their 2nd
 choice is promoted to 1st choice and is not removed until after *it* loses.
  but for it to lose, it is counted and, by the dumb IRV rules, is considered
 to come up short.

No. As Abd ul pointed out your claim is true only when the voter's 2nd
choice has not already been eliminated as happens *very* frequently in
IRV when a majority-favorite candidate is eliminated before the final
counting round or when any voters' 2nd choice candidates are
eliminated prior to his first choice being eliminated.

This is the main reason why the IRV/STV counting method is so
fundamentally unfair - because it does not treat all voters' ballots
equally.

It seems funny to me that you call candidates it.


 do you mean their 2nd choice is not counted because their first choice loses
 in the final round?

Yes, that too is a major reason why a majority of voters may prefer a
candidate who is eliminated early on in IRV/STV methods.

  that goes without saying, but that's the dumb IRV
 rules.  that is an *arbitrary* threshold imposed upon IRV, that 1st choices
 count and *anything* below the 1st choice makes *no* difference until it
 gets bumped off and every other choice gets bumped up.

 and this is what makes
 IRV/STV such a fundamentally unfair system that tends to elect extreme
 right or left candidates while eliminating the majority favored
 candidates.

 it tends to elect the candidate from the larger subgroup (in Burlington,
 Prog vs. Dem) of the larger group (left vs. right).

Yes. I agree. If there had been more extreme rightists, the rightist
candidate would have won over the majority-favorite centrist Democrat
in Burlington and the Progressive candidate would have been the
spoiler instead of the Republican candidate.

 if the fringes were
 smaller than the center, it would elect the center candidate.  but, at least

The majority of voters favored the centrist candidate who was
eliminated, typical IRV/STV style.

I think you are referring to first choice votes only.

 if you use the mayoral vote as a measure, in Burlington Vermont, there are
 more Progs than Dems.

Again, you are considering first choice votes only, which would have
been far different if voters in Burlington had not been falsely misled
by Fair Vote propaganda into thinking that it was safe for them to
vote their conscience or vote sincerely which is certainly a
recipe for a majority of voters to get their least desired outcome in
IRV/STV methods.


 but the elimination criterion is faulty in IRV, I KNOW THAT (next time you
 call me an IRV proponent, i am going to remind you that you don't read).

Really!! So you expect me to memorize all your emails from weeks ago
and in your illogical mind if I fail to memorize all *your* emails,
that means that I don't read!! Well it's no wonder then that you
don't understand how IRV/STV work then and have to be repeatedly told
how it works by Abd ul and myself.

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Terry Bouricius
Kathy,

You need to learn the terminology for election experts to understand you. 
You can't use the term majority-favorite to when you mean 
Condorcet-winner. They mean different things, and your statements below 
are confusing (and false), simply because you are using terms incorrectly.

For the record, I am indeed a supporter of Condorcet methods, and would 
support their adoption. However, I think IRV is sufficiently superior to 
plurality voting to also deserve active support...And ultimately I think 
IRV is more achievable for public elections than Condorcet methods, simply 
because Americans are familiar with and accepting of traditional runoff 
systems (TTR), which suffer all of the same non-monotonicity, and other 
shortcomings as IRV that Kathy focuses on.

Terry Bouricius

- Original Message - 
From: Kathy Dopp kathy.d...@gmail.com
To: robert bristow-johnson r...@audioimagination.com
Cc: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Sent: Thursday, January 14, 2010 1:17 PM
Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality


On Thu, Jan 14, 2010 at 12:34 PM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:



I'm glad to hear you don't support IRV/STV methods.

 There are several scenarios where voters' marked 2nd choices are never
 counted, even when their first choice loses,

 if their 1st choice loses at some time before the final round, their 2nd
 choice is promoted to 1st choice and is not removed until after *it* 
 loses.
 but for it to lose, it is counted and, by the dumb IRV rules, is 
 considered
 to come up short.

No. As Abd ul pointed out your claim is true only when the voter's 2nd
choice has not already been eliminated as happens *very* frequently in
IRV when a majority-favorite candidate is eliminated before the final
counting round or when any voters' 2nd choice candidates are
eliminated prior to his first choice being eliminated.

This is the main reason why the IRV/STV counting method is so
fundamentally unfair - because it does not treat all voters' ballots
equally.

It seems funny to me that you call candidates it.


 do you mean their 2nd choice is not counted because their first choice 
 loses
 in the final round?

Yes, that too is a major reason why a majority of voters may prefer a
candidate who is eliminated early on in IRV/STV methods.

 that goes without saying, but that's the dumb IRV
 rules. that is an *arbitrary* threshold imposed upon IRV, that 1st 
 choices
 count and *anything* below the 1st choice makes *no* difference until it
 gets bumped off and every other choice gets bumped up.

 and this is what makes
 IRV/STV such a fundamentally unfair system that tends to elect extreme
 right or left candidates while eliminating the majority favored
 candidates.

 it tends to elect the candidate from the larger subgroup (in Burlington,
 Prog vs. Dem) of the larger group (left vs. right).

Yes. I agree. If there had been more extreme rightists, the rightist
candidate would have won over the majority-favorite centrist Democrat
in Burlington and the Progressive candidate would have been the
spoiler instead of the Republican candidate.

 if the fringes were
 smaller than the center, it would elect the center candidate. but, at 
 least

The majority of voters favored the centrist candidate who was
eliminated, typical IRV/STV style.

I think you are referring to first choice votes only.

 if you use the mayoral vote as a measure, in Burlington Vermont, there 
 are
 more Progs than Dems.

Again, you are considering first choice votes only, which would have
been far different if voters in Burlington had not been falsely misled
by Fair Vote propaganda into thinking that it was safe for them to
vote their conscience or vote sincerely which is certainly a
recipe for a majority of voters to get their least desired outcome in
IRV/STV methods.


 but the elimination criterion is faulty in IRV, I KNOW THAT (next time 
 you
 call me an IRV proponent, i am going to remind you that you don't 
 read).

Really!! So you expect me to memorize all your emails from weeks ago
and in your illogical mind if I fail to memorize all *your* emails,
that means that I don't read!! Well it's no wonder then that you
don't understand how IRV/STV work then and have to be repeatedly told
how it works by Abd ul and myself.

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org
http://electionmathematics.org
http://kathydopp.com/serendipity/

Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting
http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantRunoffVotingFlaws.pdf

Voters Have Reason to Worry
http://utahcountvotes.org/UT/UtahCountVotes-ThadHall-Response.pdf

Checking election outcome accuracy --- Post-election audit sampling
http://electionmathematics.org/em-audits/US/PEAuditSamplingMethods.pdf

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread robert bristow-johnson


On Jan 14, 2010, at 1:12 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:

We know that we can't have a system with all the properties that we  
might independently desire. Consequently, we compare systems  
overall, looking not just at their list of properties met and  
unmet, but at the implications for voter behavior, nomination,  
campaigns, and so on.


Those implications have been widely discussed on this list, and I  
won't try to repeat those discussions. Suffice it to say that to  
elevate a single criterion, CW or LNH or other, to the sole  
criterion by which we judge methods just doesn't cut it.


with a single winner election (like mayor or some other executive, or  
a single representative)


with the arbitrary assumption pleasing the majority is better than  
pleasing the minority, i don't understand what other arbitrary value  
trumps that of electing the Condorcet winner if such exists.   
pathologies can happen in a cycle, but, as i have wondered aloud here  
before, i wonder how often it would really happen for a Condorcet  
cycle to occur in real elections.


simply, if a Condorcet winner exists, and your election authority  
elevates to office someone else, that elected person is rejected by a  
majority of the electorate.  what other democratic value papers over  
that flaw?  LNH?  monotonicity?


like the popular vote is the gold standard we use to judge how well  
the Electoral College does, it seems to me that the Condocet  
criterion is the gold standard to use to judge how well some other  
method works.  in both cases it seems logical to ditch the  
experimental method and just use the gold standard.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread robert bristow-johnson


oops.  forgot to finish a sentence.

On Jan 14, 2010, at 1:12 PM, Jonathan Lundell wrote:

We know that we can't have a system with all the properties that we  
might independently desire. Consequently, we compare systems  
overall, looking not just at their list of properties met and  
unmet, but at the implications for voter behavior, nomination,  
campaigns, and so on.


Those implications have been widely discussed on this list, and I  
won't try to repeat those discussions. Suffice it to say that to  
elevate a single criterion, CW or LNH or other, to the sole  
criterion by which we judge methods just doesn't cut it.


with a single winner election (like mayor or some other executive, or  
a single representative), the elected candidate should be considered  
better or superior to every other, any other, candidate propped  
up against him/her.  if it's not about democracy, then we can think  
up other tests of merit, like a written civil-service like exam.  or  
age or years of experience.  or we could get Machiavellian about it  
and give it to the candidate with more guns and fighters.  or we  
could have them arm wrestle or throw darts.  but, i cannot imagine,  
in a democracy, a criterion for better other than preferred by more  
voters than voters who prefer the other candidate.


with the arbitrary assumption pleasing the majority is better than  
pleasing the minority, i don't understand what other arbitrary value  
trumps that of electing the Condorcet winner if such exists.   
pathologies can happen in a cycle, but, as i have wondered aloud here  
before, i wonder how often it would really happen for a Condorcet  
cycle to occur in real elections.


simply, if a Condorcet winner exists, and your election authority  
elevates to office someone else, that elected person is rejected by a  
majority of the electorate.  what other democratic value papers over  
that flaw?  LNH?  monotonicity?


like the popular vote is the gold standard we use to judge how well  
the Electoral College does, it seems to me that the Condocet  
criterion is the gold standard to use to judge how well some other  
method works.  in both cases it seems logical to ditch the  
experimental method and just use the gold standard.


--

r b-j  r...@audioimagination.com

Imagination is more important than knowledge.





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Kathy Dopp
On Thu, Jan 14, 2010 at 1:44 PM, robert bristow-johnson
r...@audioimagination.com wrote:

 On Jan 14, 2010, at 1:17 PM, Kathy Dopp wrote:

 On Thu, Jan 14, 2010 at 12:34 PM, robert bristow-johnson
 r...@audioimagination.com wrote:



 I'm glad to hear you don't support IRV/STV methods.

 not over Condorcet.

 i dunno what else you could have drawn from either my posts here or at the
 FairVote.org site where i took on Rob Ritchie *several* times (and i've seen
 you there, too).

My entire life's focus is not in following all election methods debates.


 There are several scenarios where voters' marked 2nd choices are never
 counted, even when their first choice loses,

 if their 1st choice loses at some time before the final round, their 2nd
 choice is promoted to 1st choice and is not removed until after *it*
 loses.
  but for it to lose, it is counted and, by the dumb IRV rules, is
 considered
 to come up short.

 No. As Abd ul pointed out your claim is true only when the voter's 2nd
 choice has not already been eliminated as happens *very* frequently in
 IRV when a majority-favorite candidate is eliminated before the final
 counting round or when any voters' 2nd choice candidates are
 eliminated prior to his first choice being eliminated.

 This is the main reason why the IRV/STV counting method is so
 fundamentally unfair - because it does not treat all voters' ballots
 equally.

 It seems funny to me that you call candidates it.


 i call the vote or ranking it.

It loses is what you said, clearly referring to candidates that
voters rank. Reread to see.

 The majority of voters favored the centrist candidate who was
 eliminated, typical IRV/STV style.

 that happened in Burlington in 2009 (but not in 2006).  that failure is what
 has been my sole concern about this whole thing for 10 months.

Great.

 if you use the mayoral vote as a measure, in Burlington Vermont, there
 are
 more Progs than Dems.

 Again, you are considering first choice votes only, which would have
 been far different if voters in Burlington had not been falsely misled
 by Fair Vote propaganda into thinking that it was safe for them to
 vote their conscience or vote sincerely which is certainly a
 recipe for a majority of voters to get their least desired outcome in
 IRV/STV methods.


 but the elimination criterion is faulty in IRV, I KNOW THAT (next time
 you
 call me an IRV proponent, i am going to remind you that you don't
 read).

Reread. Unlike you stating You don't read as if you have all-seeing
ability to know that I never read, I **never** said You are an IRV
proponent. Please try to stop confusing your own imagination with
reality and notice what I actually wrote and what you actually have
ability to know, when responding to emails.


 about this, Kathy, i don't believe your veracity at all.  since March of
 2009 (when Burlington IRV failed to elect the Condorcet winner and all sorts

OK Robert, I guess I won't argue anymore with your claim that you know
that I don't read even though you have never once met me in person
and know zero about what I spend my time doing.  Fine, you believe
that you have Godlike abilities to know all and see all about what I
do with my time inside your own imagination at least.  It's clear.

 repeatedly, i keep wondering why folks like you pass over Condorcet, that in

folks like me who don't read you mean? Or exactly what slurr are you
now hurling at me since you obviously never asked me whether or not I
support the Condorcet method, you seem to rely once again on your own
imagination to proclaim what my position is, which you obviously
imagine you know better than I do.

In my own imagination, I **do** support the Condorcet method, although
I don't know how to solve the Condorcet cycles or how often, if ever,
they might occur.

However, I see that once again you are certain that you know more
about myself, what I do, and my own positions, than I do via your own
imagination, which it seems, you feel no need to verify with any
outside facts.


 but my position here has *never* been as a proponent of IRV, but a proponent
 of Condorcet and the ranked ballot.

 i've said multiple times that IRV transferred the burden of having to vote
 strategically from the majority (in Burlington, that would be the liberal
 that would have to split their votes between Prog and Dem) to the minority
 (in Burlington that would be the GOP Prog-haters that discovered that their
 primary vote for their favorite candidate was instrumental in electing the
 candidate they least preferred).

GREAT. Well we agree on many things, even if I think you are slightly
delusional for thinking you know so much more about me than I do re.
my not reading and my positions on election methods.

Kathy

 --

 r b-j                  ...@audioimagination.com

 Imagination is more important than knowledge.








-- 

Kathy Dopp

Town of Colonie, NY 12304
phone 518-952-4030
cell 518-505-0220

http://utahcountvotes.org

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Terry Bouricius
Response to Robert's statement...
I guess I still haven't heard a good justification for why the Condorcet 
winner, if one exists, should *ever* be rejected as the elected winner.
...

Imagine this scenario. ..

A highly polarized electorate with a three candidate race. Only two candidates 
are seen by the media and the public as viable, with 49% favoring candidate A 
and 46% favoring B, and 5% favoring C slightly over A. Most voters don't know 
much about C, but C has carefully avoided alienating any constituency by only 
stressing his likeability, rather than issues. However while the supporters of 
both A and B don't think much of C they rank C second because they subscribe to 
the anybody but X notion. The A supporters all rank ACB, while the B 
supporters all rank BCA and the C voters all rank CAB

49 ACB
46 BCA
  5 CAB

In a traditional runoff or IRV, A would win over B, after C's elimination by 54 
to 46. I think that is a reasonable expression of the public will though not 
the only possible one.

With Condorcet, 
C would defeat A by 51 to 49
and C would defeat B by 54 to 46

Thus C is the Condorcet winner. 

It is certainly justifiable to argue that C is the rightful winner. But it is 
not unreasonable to say that C is not the rightful winner, since 95% of the 
voters are highly dissatisfied with C being elected. This is where the Range 
voting utility advocates enter the fray. My point is merely that the 
Condorcet-winner criterion is desirable in most cases, but not the only 
legitimate, nor ultimate criterion.

Terry Bouricius
Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality

2010-01-14 Thread Jonathan Lundell
On Jan 14, 2010, at 11:00 AM, robert bristow-johnson wrote:

 simply, if a Condorcet winner exists, and your election authority elevates to 
 office someone else, that elected person is rejected by a majority of the 
 electorate.  what other democratic value papers over that flaw?  LNH?  
 monotonicity?

Terry covered pretty much what I have to say on the subject.

 
 like the popular vote is the gold standard we use to judge how well the 
 Electoral College does, it seems to me that the Condocet criterion is the 
 gold standard to use to judge how well some other method works.  in both 
 cases it seems logical to ditch the experimental method and just use the 
 gold standard.

But it's not (the gold standard) as things stand now. 

Sure, we should ditch the EC and move to national IRV ;-). But with the EC in 
place, a candidate will (justifiably) campaign for electoral votes. In 2008, it 
was a waste of funds for McCain to campaign in (say) New York, Massachusetts or 
California, so he didn't bother to compete for a bigger share of the popular 
vote, which presumably he could have gotten by spending some campaign cash. 
Obama, on the other hand, was motivated to spend at least *some* time 
campaigning in those states, if for no other reason but that they were a good 
*source* of funds for him.

Regardless, you'll recall that the big fuss in 2000 wasn't really over the 
popular vs electoral vote, mainly, I think, because most people understood 
(from campaign coverage) that the electoral vote was what counted.

To be clear, I repeat: I don't think that's the way it should be. But we must 
interpret voter and candidate behavior in the context of the existing rules.

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


  1   2   >