Re: [EM] Fwd: Is it professional?

2013-06-24 Thread James Gilmour
 David L WetzellSent: Monday, June 24, 2013 4:19 PM

 Most IRV in real world limits the rankings to 3 candidates per voter.  

In real world?  Evidence please  -  on a WORLD basis..

I have never encountered such limits in any IRV election.  But then, I don't 
live in the USA.

Some 3-only limits are imposed because of the limitations of the out-of-date 
equipment used to tally paper ballots.

James Gilmour
Edinburgh, Scotland




---
avast! Antivirus: Outbound message clean.
Virus Database (VPS): 130624-1, 24/06/2013
Tested on: 24/06/2013 17:17:08
avast! - copyright (c) 1988-2013 AVAST Software.
http://www.avast.com




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] proportional constraints - help needed

2013-02-06 Thread James Gilmour
Although you do not appear to favour STV-PR to address your problem, I should 
have made it clear in my post, copied below, that
there is only ONE election.  That is to determine the set of successful 
candidates who have to be ordered for the list.  There is
then a succession of COUNTS of the same ballot papers, with the number of 
vacancies diminished by one at each successive count and
the candidate defeated in the previous count omitted.

Apologies if my lack of specificity in the original wording caused any 
confusion or misunderstanding.   
James


 -Original Message-
 From: James Gilmour [mailto:jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk] 
 Sent: Tuesday, February 05, 2013 11:49 PM
 To: 'Jonathan Lundell'; 'Peter Zbornik'
 Cc: 'election-meth...@electorama.com'
 Subject: RE: [EM] proportional constraints - help needed
 
 
  Jonathan Lundell   Sent: Tuesday, February 05, 2013 6:40 
 PM There is, 
  I think, an underlying misconception here, namely that STV order of 
  election can be interpreted as a ranking of level of support. It's 
  not, in the general case.
 
 Jonathan is absolutely right.  If you want lists ordered by 
 relative support, you need to adopt a procedure like that 
 recommended by Colin Rosenstiel and used by some UK political 
 parties when they have to select ordered lists for 
 closed-list party-PR elections.
 
 First you use ordinary STV-PR to elect the required total 
 number of candidates.  Then you conduct a series of STV-PR 
 elections, each for one vacancy less than the preceding 
 election.  The unsuccessful candidate takes the lowest vacant 
 place on the ordered list.  Continue until you run-off 
 between the top-two for the second-last place.
 
 For full details, see:
   http://www.crosenstiel.webspace.virginmedia.com/stv/orderstv.htm
 and   
   http://www.crosenstiel.webspace.virginmedia.com/stv/ordstvdt.htm
 
 The second one includes a constraint for candidate's sex.
 
 James Gilmour
 
 



---
avast! Antivirus: Outbound message clean.
Virus Database (VPS): 130206-1, 06/02/2013
Tested on: 06/02/2013 23:18:27
avast! - copyright (c) 1988-2013 AVAST Software.
http://www.avast.com




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] proportional constraints - help needed

2013-02-05 Thread James Gilmour
 Jonathan Lundell   Sent: Tuesday, February 05, 2013 6:40 PM
 There is, I think, an underlying misconception here, namely 
 that STV order of election can be interpreted as a ranking of 
 level of support. It's not, in the general case.

Jonathan is absolutely right.  If you want lists ordered by relative support, 
you need to adopt a procedure like that recommended by
Colin Rosenstiel and used by some UK political parties when they have to select 
ordered lists for closed-list party-PR elections.

First you use ordinary STV-PR to elect the required total number of candidates. 
 Then you conduct a series of STV-PR elections, each
for one vacancy less than the preceding election.  The unsuccessful candidate 
takes the lowest vacant place on the ordered list.
Continue until you run-off between the top-two for the second-last place.

For full details, see:  
  http://www.crosenstiel.webspace.virginmedia.com/stv/orderstv.htm  
and 
  http://www.crosenstiel.webspace.virginmedia.com/stv/ordstvdt.htm

The second one includes a constraint for candidate's sex.

James Gilmour




---
avast! Antivirus: Outbound message clean.
Virus Database (VPS): 130205-0, 05/02/2013
Tested on: 05/02/2013 23:49:22
avast! - copyright (c) 1988-2013 AVAST Software.
http://www.avast.com




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Majority-Judgement using adjectives versus alphabeticalscales versus numerical ranges.

2012-12-06 Thread James Gilmour
Most of this discussion, if it relates to public elections, ignores the 
electors.  It takes no account of the real levels of literacy and numeracy.  In 
the UK approximately 25% of adults have a literacy level below that expected 
for an adult.  I do not think the overall situation in the USA will be any 
better.

I do not think the majority of electors would be happy with negative numbers.  
Opinion polling organisations tend to use scales graded 1 - 5 or 1 - 10.

We do have experience in Scotland of voters ranking candidates in order of 
preference in STV-PR elections for our 32 local government councils.  Details 
of the numbers of preferences marked, by ward and by ballot box (= Polling 
Station = part of a Polling District), are available on the 32 websites of the 
councils.  The full ballot data (preference profiles) for all 353 wards will be 
available early in 2013.

James Gilmour


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Juho Laatu
 Sent: Thursday, December 06, 2012 11:23 PM
 To: EM list
 Subject: Re: [EM] Majority-Judgement using adjectives versus 
 alphabeticalscales versus numerical ranges.
 
 
 On 6.12.2012, at 23.54, ⸘Ŭalabio‽ wrote:
 
  ¡Hello!
  
  ¿How fare you?
  
  Yesterday, I noted that Majority-Judgements does not 
 work if we have 
  too many adjectives because we have only so many adjectives 
 and voters 
  might confuse adjectives too close in meaning..  ¿Would an 
  alphabetical scale be acceptable?:
  
  In the United States of America, we grade students 
 using letters:
  
  A+
  A
  A-
  B+
  B
  B-
  C+
  C
  C-
  D+
  D
  D-
  F+
  F
  F-
  
  I have 2 questions grading candidates on this scale.  1 
 question is 
  for people not in the United States of America.  The other 
 question is 
  for everyone:
  
  People outside the United States of America:
  
  ¿Do you Understand this Scale?
 
 Very understandable. If some values should be considered 
 unacceptable, then that category should be pointed out.
 
  
  For everyone:
  
  ¿Is this scale acceptable to you?
  
  Followup question:
  
  If this scale is not acceptable to you, ¿why is it not 
 acceptable to 
  you?
  
  With 15 grades, this scale is not very different from 
 the numerical 
  ranges of 0 to 9 or negative -9 to positive +9.  This raises the 
  question:
  
  ¿Why not just use the ranges 0 to 9 or negative -9 to 
 positive +9 
  instead?
 
 Each country could use those values (letters or numbers) that 
 people are most familiar with. If you want to have universal 
 coverage, then numbers are good since they heve the same 
 meaning and people are familiar with them everyehere.
 
 It depends on the type of election if -n to +n is better 
 than 0 to n or 1 to n. If there is an approval cutoff 
 or unacceptable values, then the scale can be from a to b 
 to c (b can be 0 or a positive number). Since most number 
 systems are based on 10, ranges that are in one way or 
 another based on that number are good.
 
 I guess low values are usually worse than high values, but 
 one could also use ranking style values where 1 is the best value.
 
 Juho
 



-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com
Version: 2012.0.2221 / Virus Database: 2634/5439 - Release Date: 12/05/12



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread James Gilmour
  I think Plurality can be claimed to be the ideal method for the 
  single-member districts of a two-party system, but then one should 
  maybe also think that third parties should not be allowed  to run, and 
  we should stick to the same two parties forever.
  
  I don't get it.
  
  of course, if there are only two candidates, there is no problem with 
  Plurality (because it's also a Majority).
  
  so how is Plurality so flawed if we accept that a two-party system is 
  fine and dandy?  if not Third parties, for Independents?
  
  what is the scenario with two parties where FPTP is so flawed?
 
 I think you already said it. If you want a system that allows 
 also third parties and independents take part in the 
 election, then Plurality is flawed. Only if you think that 
 third parties and independents should nor run, and there 
 should be only two parties, then Plurality is fine.

These contributions to this discussion take an extremely narrow view of 
representation of voters as it is clear this discussion is
not about a single-winner election (state governor, city mayor) but about 
electing representative assemblies like state legislatures
and city councils.  There can be major problems of representation if such 
representative assemblies are elected by FPTP from
single-member districts even when there are only two parties.

Even when the electorates of the single-member districts are as near equal as 
possible and even when the turnouts are near equal,
FPTP in single-member districts can deliver highly unrepresentative results if 
the support for the two parties is concentrated in
particular districts -  as it is in most electorates.  Thus party A that wins 
51 of the 100 seats in the assembly may win those
seats by small margins (say 550 votes to 450 votes) but party B that looses the 
election with 49 of the 100 seats may have won its
seats by overwhelming margins (say 700 votes to 300 votes).  Thus the 51 A to 
49 B result is highly unrepresentative of those who
actually voted: 42,750 for party A but 57,250 for party B.

These numbers are deliberately exaggerated to show the point, but here in the 
UK we see this effect in every UK General Election
since 1945, where the win small, loose big effect of FPTP has consistently 
benefited the Labour Party at the expense of the
Conservative Party.

And where such vote concentration exists  -  at is does everywhere  -  the 
result can be greatly influenced by where the boundaries
of the single-member districts are drawn.  Move the boundary, change the 
result.

These are fundamental defects of FPTP in single-member districts that must be 
addressed if you want your elected assemblies to be
properly representative of those who vote.

Both of these defects has greater effect if the electorates are not so equal or 
if the turnouts vary with party support (as they
certainly do in the UK).

So even when there are only two parties, FPTP is very far from fine.

James Gilmour





-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com
Version: 2012.0.2178 / Virus Database: 2425/5044 - Release Date: 06/04/12



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] My summary of the recent discussion

2012-06-04 Thread James Gilmour

  what is the scenario with two parties where FPTP is so flawed?

  Only if you think that 
  third parties and independents should nor run, and there 
  should be only two parties, then Plurality is fine.

  On 4.6.2012, at 13.49, James Gilmour wrote: 
  These contributions to this discussion take an extremely narrow view 
  of representation of voters as it is clear this discussion is not 
  about a single-winner election (state governor, city mayor) but about 
  electing representative assemblies like state legislatures and city 
  councils.  There can be major problems of representation if such 
  representative assemblies are elected by FPTP from single-member 
  districts even when there are only two parties.
  
  Even when the electorates of the single-member districts are as near 
  equal as possible and even when the turnouts are near equal, FPTP in 
  single-member districts can deliver highly unrepresentative results if 
  the support for the two parties is concentrated in particular 
  districts -  as it is in most electorates.  Thus party A that wins 51 
  of the 100 seats in the assembly may win those seats by small margins 
  (say 550 votes to 450 votes) but party B that looses the election with 
  49 of the 100 seats may have won its seats by overwhelming margins 
  (say 700 votes to 300 votes).  Thus the 51 A to 49 B result is highly 
  unrepresentative of those who actually voted: 42,750 for party A but 
  57,250 for party B.
  
  These numbers are deliberately exaggerated to show the point, but here 
  in the UK we see this effect in every UK General Election since 1945, 
  where the win small, loose big effect of FPTP has consistently 
  benefited the Labour Party at the expense of the Conservative Party.
  
  And where such vote concentration exists  -  at is does everywhere  -  
  the result can be greatly influenced by where the boundaries of the 
  single-member districts are drawn.  Move the boundary, change the 
  result.
  
  These are fundamental defects of FPTP in single-member districts that 
  must be addressed if you want your elected assemblies to be properly 
  representative of those who vote.
  
  Both of these defects has greater effect if the electorates are not so 
  equal or if the turnouts vary with party support (as they certainly do 
  in the UK).
  
  So even when there are only two parties, FPTP is very far from fine.


 Juho   Sent: Monday, June 04, 2012 4:06 PM 
 Yes, that makes sense. FPTP in single-member districts is not 
 fair in the sense that it gives only approximate results (due 
 to the inaccuracy of counting the seats in single-member 
 districts) and is vulnerable to gerrymandering.

It is not a question of not fair (which can be a highly subjective 
assessment), it is simply that the result is not properly
representative.  And the distortion is not due to inaccuracy  -  the defect 
is inherent in the system as it is based on
single-member districts.  And it is a defect, given the purpose of the election 
 -  to elect a representative assembly..

Such a system is vulnerable to gerrymandering, i.e. to the DELIBERATE 
manipulation of the district boundaries.  But the real point
is that these boundary effects occur even when there is no gerrymandering, i.e. 
no deliberate manipulation.


 A system that counts the proportions at national level 
 (typically a multi-party system) would be more accurate. Also 
 gerrymandering can be avoided this way.

Yes, the votes could be summed at national level and the seats allocated at 
national level.  But you do not need to go to national
level to achieve proper representation.  Where the electors also want some 
guarantee of local representation, a satisfactory
compromise can be achieved with a much more modest 'district magnitude' than 
one national district.


 The discussed proposal of changing the Plurality/FPTP method 
 of the single-member districts to some other single-winner 
 method has still many of the discussed problems (inaccuracy, 
 gerrymandering). One could try to construct also two-party 
 systems or single-member district based systems that would 
 avoid those problems. But maybe proportional representation 
 is a more likely ideal end result. Practical reforms may 
 however start with whatever achievable steps.

All single-member district voting systems will have similar defects.  But 
remember my comments were made in direct response to the
statements quoted at the top:  (more or less) If there are only two parties, 
FPTP is fine.I think the problem with what may be
regarded achievable steps is that many contributors to this list start in the 
wrong place.  Elections are for electors  - so
where the objective is to elect a 'representative assembly' (state legislature, 
city council), the first requirement should be that
the voting system delivers an assembly that it is properly representative  -  
all else is secondary.

James







-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG

Re: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?

2012-02-19 Thread James Gilmour
David L Wetzell Sent: Saturday, February 18, 2012 8:21 PM
 If voters can help elect a 3rd party more easily then it 
 doesn't matter if there's a stronger role for party hierarchy 
 in the determination of their party's candidate.   

This is far from the reality  -  it matters a great deal.  Most parties are 
coalitions, to greater or lesser degrees.  For example,
here in the UK we still have left and right wings within the Labour Party 
and we have pro-EU and anti-EU wings with the
Conservative Party.  If the party hierarchy can impose one political viewpoint 
by putting candidates from one wing of the party in
all the winnable places on the party's list the many of the supporters of that 
party will be faced with a hold your nose choice  -
either vote for they party's list dominated by the other wing or vote against 
the party altogether and let the opposition in.  And
that's not theoretical  -  we have seen it done here in the UK where, sadly, we 
do have some party-list PR elections.


 dlw: All that is true, but it does not change my point that 
 election reform got on the ballot in large part because the 
 use of quasi-PR in more local elections helped the LibDems 
 to continue to rival the two biggest parties.  When third 
 parties can gain foot-holds, there's inevitably going to be 
 pressure away from FPTP.  

This is also very far from the reality.  The role of the Liberal Democrats in 
UK-level politics has not been fostered by the use of
PR voting systems (of various kinds) in some sub-UK elections.  The two things 
are not at all related and certainly had nothing to
do with preparing any imaged climate for the AV referendum.

James Gilmour


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?

2012-02-17 Thread James Gilmour
But why would you want all these differences and complications?

If you are going to use STV-PR for some of these elections, why not use STV-PR 
for all of these elections to the various
representative assemblies (councils, state legislatures, US House of 
Representatives, US Senate).  STV-PR works OK in both
partisan and non-partisan elections, so it should give fair and proper 
representation of the VOTERS in all these different
elections.

Of course, with districts returning only 3 to 5 members, the proportionality 
and direct representation MAY be a little limited, but
if small numbers are needed to make the system acceptable to the vested 
interests, then so be it.  STV-PR with 3, 4 or 5 member
districts is greatly to be preferred to plurality in single-member districts 
and to plurality at large.  We had to accept local
government wards electing only 3 or 4 councillors as part of our STV-PR package 
 -  that's practical politics.  But that reform has
transformed our local government  -  no more one-party states.

James Gilmour


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of David L Wetzell
 Sent: Friday, February 17, 2012 2:49 PM
 To: EM
 Subject: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?
 
 
 It seems to me that a common sense solution would be to base 
 which gets used on the propensity for voters to be informed 
 about the elections.
 
 Also, the two types seem to be bundled with different types 
 of quotas.  STV gets marketed with the droop quota here in 
 the US.  I'm not complaining because it's good to simplify 
 things.  But if STV were bundled with Droop then 3-seat LR 
 Hare might prove handy to make sure that 3rd parties get a 
 constructive role to play in US politics.
 
 So I propose that 3-5 seat STV with a droop quota, perhaps 
 using AV in a first step to simplify and shorten the 
 vote-counting and transferring process, for US congressional 
 elections or city council elections and 3-seat LR Hare for 
 state representative and aldermen elections.  The latter two 
 elections are less important and get less media coverage and 
 voter attention.  Is it reasonable to expect voters to rank 
 multiple candidates in an election where they often simply 
 vote their party line?  Why not keep it simple and use the 
 mix of Droop and Hare quotas to both keep the system's 
 duopolistic tendencies and to make the duopoly contested?
 
 It seems to me that most folks think the choice is between 
 ranked choices or party-list PR.  I think it is a matter of 
 context and that both can be useful, especially when no 
 explicit party-list is required for a 3-seat LR Hare 
 election.  The vice-candidates who would hold the extra seats 
 a party wins could either be selected after the victory or 
 specified before hand.  
 
 So what do you think?
 
 I'm keeping the seat numbers down because I accept that those 
 in power aren't going to want an EU multi-party system and 
 I'm not sure they're wrong about that, plus the US is used to 
 voting the candidate and having their representative and they 
 could keep that if there are relatively few seats per election.
 
 dlw
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?

2012-02-17 Thread James Gilmour
I don't see why anyone would want to use a party-list voting system when there 
are more voter-centred alternatives that fit much
better with the political cultures of countries like USA, Canada, UK.  Why 
anyone would want to use the Hare quota when, with
preferential voting, it can distort the proportionality  - in a way that Droop 
does not.  Why anyone would want to restrict the
voting system to 3-seat districts instead of adopting a flexible approach to 
district magnitude to fit local geography and
recognised communities..
James Gilmour

-Original Message-
From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
[mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On Behalf Of David L
Wetzell
Sent: Friday, February 17, 2012 9:21 PM
To: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Subject: Re: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?


I give a rebuttal to the Electoral Reform Society's assessment of party-list PR 
for the case of 3-seat LR Hare. 
http://anewkindofparty.blogspot.com/2011/05/electoral-reform-society-united-kingdom.html
 

dlw


On Fri, Feb 17, 2012 at 2:54 PM, David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com wrote:




From: Richard Fobes electionmeth...@votefair.org
To: election-meth...@electorama.com
Cc: 
Date: Fri, 17 Feb 2012 12:01:16 -0800 

Subject: Re: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?

On 2/17/2012 6:49 AM, David L Wetzell wrote:


... 

It seems to me that most folks think the choice is between ranked

choices or party-list PR.  ... 


So what do you think?



I don't see this as an either/or choice,


dlw: U2 apparently are not among most folks...
 

nor do I see a viable both option being suggested.



dlw: viability is a low-blow at this stage, but I guess it's a blow I use quite 
often.   


So I'll again suggest VoteFair ranking:

VoteFair ranking uses ranked choices (1-2-3 ballots and pairwise counting...) 
for identifying the most popular candidate -- for
filling the first seat in a legislative district.

VoteFair ranking fills the second district-based seat with the second-most 
representative candidate.  In the U.S., even without
asking voters to indicate a party preference, that would usually be the most 
popular candidate from the opposite party (i.e. the
opposite party compared to the first-seat winner).

To further increase proportionality, VoteFair ranking fills some proportional 
seats based on the favorite party of the voters.
(Whichever party has the biggest gap between voter proportion and filled-seat 
proportion wins the next seat.)

We don't have to choose between proportionality (PR) and ranked methods.  We 
can get both.  And in a U.S.-compatible way.

If election-method reform is to happen in the U.S., it has to merge with the 
reality of the two-party system.  And I believe it
should accommodate third parties only to the extent that voters are unable to 
regain control of the two main parties.



dlw: I agree with the reality of the 2-party system.  I also believe that we 
need to make the case that our 2-party system will work
much, much better if we give 3rd parties a constructive role to play in it.  
Giving them access to one-third of the seats in the
state assembly so they get to determine which major party is in power in that 
body every two years is such a constructive role.  It
will give folks more exit threat from the two major parties, thereby making 
both of them more responsive to the moving center.


As for STV, going beyond two seats easily produces unfair results.  And in the 
U.S. the results also would be quite unstable (i.e.
not mesh well with the current two-party system).



Can you elaborate?
I don't see why 3-5 seat STV with a droop quota wouldn't have results like what 
you described that would maintain yet transform the
US's 2-party system.

dlw


Richard Fobes




-- Forwarded message --
From: Jameson Quinn jameson.qu...@gmail.com
To: David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com
Cc: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
Date: Fri, 17 Feb 2012 14:35:58 -0600
Subject: Re: [EM] JQ wrt SODA
If first-mover is all that counts, then I'm afraid we're stuck with plurality. 
Obviously, I hope and believe that's not true. 

Jameson


2012/2/17 David L Wetzell wetze...@gmail.com


IRV's got a first mover advantage over SODA and to catch up you need to 
convince someone like Soros to help you market it.  It
wouldn't matter if you got the whole EM list to agree with you that it was 
hunky-dory.   

But in the context of a 2-party dominated system, there aren't as many serious 
candidates and so what relative advantages there are
of SODA over IRV will be less, which then makes the first-mover marketing 
problem more significant, especially if IRV can be souped
up with the seemingly slight modification of the use of a limited form of 
approval voting in the first stage.

dlw

On Fri, Feb 17, 2012 at 12:27 PM, 
election-methods-requ...@lists.electorama.com wrote:


Send Election-Methods mailing list submissions to
   election

Re: [EM] STV vs Party-list PR, could context matter?

2012-02-17 Thread James Gilmour
David L Wetzell   Sent: Friday, February 17, 2012 7:31 PM
  James Gilmour: But why would you want all these differences 
  and complications?
 
 dlw: Because context matters. 

I have great difficulty in believing that there are such context specific 
differences.  I could believe that there are differences
in the hostility of the political parties to proposals for reform of the voting 
system at different levels of government and that
reforms that the parties might accept at one level would not be acceptable at 
another  - especially their own election!


 dlw: 1. There are benefits to party-list PR, relative to STV. 

I do not agree that there are any benefits of any party-PR voting system that 
outweigh the benefits to the voters of STV-PR.
Elections are for electors  -  or at least, they should be  -  and to change 
that balance in favour of the voters should be one of
the key objectives of any reform of a voting system.


  JG: We had to accept local government wards electing only 3 or 
  4 councillors as part of our STV-PR package  -  that's 
  practical politics.  But that reform has transformed our 
  local government  -  no more one-party states.
 
 
 dlw: Undoubtedly, and this is what made the AV referendum 
 possible, no doubt.

The reform of the voting system for local government in Scotland in 2007 had 
absolutely nothing to do with the 2011 UK referendum on
AV (= IRV, not approval voting).  THE problem with the AV referendum was that 
no serious reformer wanted AV.  Some party
politicians wanted AV, but far more party politicians (especially 
Conservatives) were opposed to any reform at all.  The Liberal
Democrats (whose party policy is for STV-PR) decided that a referendum on AV 
was the best they could extract from the Conservatives
in the negotiations to form the coalition government.  The negotiating teams 
were under a great deal of pressure and wanted to
achieve an agreement before the UK financial markets opened on the Monday 
morning after the Thursday election.  

James Gilmour


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Utilitarianism and Perfectionism.

2012-02-09 Thread James Gilmour
 Juho LaatuSent: Wednesday, February 08, 2012 8:29 PM

 I think I agree when I say that the first decision (in the 
 USA) is whether to make the current two-party system work 
 better or whether to aim at a multi-party system.

Juho
Don't you think you might just be starting in the wrong place?  Asking the 
wrong first question?

In a representative democracy, surely the first requirement is to ensure that 
any representative assembly (e.g. state or federal
legislature or city council) is properly representative of those who vote.  If 
when provided with the means to choose freely among
all significant viewpoints, the voters choose to cluster around two parties, 
then a two-party system will properly and fairly
represent those voters.  In other another jurisdiction, the voters may choose 
to cluster in significant proportions around three or
more parties when one would hope the voting system would be sufficiently 
sensitive for all the significant clusters to be
represented directly.

There are real examples from national and sub-national elections where 
sensitive voting systems, responding to the voters' expressed
wishes, elect representatives from several parties, but also example of where, 
despite the choice of several parties, the voters
elect representatives from only two parties.

James



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Utilitarianism and Perfectionism.

2012-02-09 Thread James Gilmour
 Juho LaatuSent: Thursday, February 09, 2012 8:07 PM
 
 As I earlier wrote, I think the US has many options on how to 
 go forward with the reform. The presidential election is 
 maybe the most interesting one.

Juho
This may be the most interesting election, but as it is almost certainly the 
most difficult in which to achieve any practical
reform, it is perhaps best left to last.  The vested interests in maintaining 
various aspects of the electoral college system are
such that much more could be achieved by turning the single-winner focus on to 
other single-winner elections.  And of course, along
with that, I would recommend changing the voting systems for all the various 
representative assemblies to make them properly
representative of those who vote.  Once these are all in place, the 
presidential election will stick out like a sore thumb.  Your
chance of reform of the voting system for that election will be much greater 
then.

James



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #4194] Re: The Occupy Movement: A Ray of Hope -- inPolitics

2011-12-11 Thread James Gilmour
The trouble with this group, judging by their website, is that, like many other 
electoral reformers in the USA, they recognise
only part of the problem: First Past the Post Voting is Obviously Flawed  -  
most definitely.
But they fail to see the bigger picture (representation of voters) and show 
almost no appreciation of where the real solution might
lie (some system of proportional representation).
Issues concerning ballot access and recounts are trivial in comparison with 
the distortion of representation of the voters  -
i.e. the relationship between votes cast and seats won.

Of course, there are some major challenges in improving the election of 
officials to single-office positions by single-winner
elections.  But the bigger picture concerns the representative assemblies  -  
the city councils and boards, the state legislatures
and both Houses of the Federal Congress.  No improvement of the voting system 
used to elect these members from single-member
districts is going to deliver real improvement of the representation of the 
voters.

James Gilmour



 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Leon Smith
 Sent: Sunday, December 11, 2011 8:29 PM
 To: electionscie...@googlegroups.com
 Cc: politics_currentevents_gr...@yahoogroups.com; 
 nygr...@yahoogroups.com; rangevot...@yahoogroups.com; EM; 
 mike+dated+1324017722.00c...@zelea.com
 Subject: Re: [EM] [CES #4194] Re: The Occupy Movement: A Ray 
 of Hope -- inPolitics
 
 
 I suppose the existence of this group is worth noting:
 
 http://reformact.org/
 
 They were a little naive about election methods at first,  
 advocating Instant Runoff,  but they have been receptive and 
 are now open for debate,  though they seem to be tentatively 
 arguing for Condorcet. And they take a comprehensive look at 
 electoral reform,  not just method.
 
 Best,
 Leon
 
 On Sun, Dec 11, 2011 at 11:14 AM, Dave Ketchum 
 da...@clarityconnect.com wrote:
  I am delighted to hear of this valuable activity.  A couple notes:
       .  local, state, federal and global levels are 
  Open_voting_network topics. All except global are important 
 in the US 
  in 2012 as a year in which serious activity is possible - 
 within the 
  framework of current laws, but without depending on 
 instantly changing 
  the laws..
       .  primary is a word used here.  It is different 
 from the primary
  elections used in the US - they are used by parties to 
 cope with the needs
  of plurality voting.
       .  Among the possibilities would be such as 
 destructive competition
  between Occupy-backing candidates in the Green and 
 Libertarian parties - if
  they split the votes of Occupy backers and thus each lost.
 
  On Dec 11, 2011, at 1:42 AM, Michael Allan wrote:
 
  Dave Ketchum wrote:
 
  Write-ins can be effective.  I hold up proof this year.  For
 
  a supervisor race:
 
   111 Rep - Joe - on the ballot from winning primary, though not
 
     campaigning.
 
   346 Con - Darlene - running as Con though unable to run as Rep+Con.
 
   540 Write-in - Bob - who gets the votes with his campaign starting
 
  18 days before election day.
 
 
  We're floating the idea within Occupy of a primary voting 
 network that 
  might help by giving independents a leg up.  It would 
 extend not only 
  across and beyond parties, but also across any number of voting 
  methods and service providers: (see also the discussion tab here) 
  
 https://wiki.occupy.net/wiki/User:Michael_Allan/RFC/Open_voting_networ
  k
 
  It's not easy to summarize, but maybe easier from the voter's POV:
 
    We won't endorse any single provider (monopoly) of primary voting
    and consensus making services.  Instead we'll maintain an open
    voting network (counter-monopoly) in which: (1) no person is
    excluded from participating in the development of alternative
    technologies and methodologies of consensus making; (2) 
 no toolset,
    platform or practice is excluded; and (3) each person may freely
    choose a provider, toolset and practices based on personal needs
    and preferences without thereby becoming isolated from 
 participants
    who make different choices.
 
  None of this is especially difficult (not technically), but 
 it's hard 
  to imagine how it could ever get started without Occupy.
 
  --
  Michael Allan
 
  Toronto, +1 416-699-9528
  http://zelea.com/
 
  Dave Ketchum wrote: ...
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV and single constraints, like gender quotas

2011-11-27 Thread James Gilmour
Peter
If you haven't already found the Church of England Regulations for STV with 
constraints, they are here:
  http://www.churchofengland.org/media/1307318/stv%20regulations.doc
These are the only published regulations for STV with constraints that I know 
of.

Your first link (below) is to a Joe Otten paper that describes one way of 
ordering a list with STV.  If that is one of the tasks
you have, you may find it useful also to look at the method devised by Colin 
Rosenstiel:
  http://www.cix.co.uk/~rosenstiel/stv/orderstv.htm 
and
  http://www.cix.co.uk/~rosenstiel/stv/ordstvdt.htm

James Gilmour


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Peter Zbornik
 Sent: Sunday, November 27, 2011 10:55 AM
 To: Election Methods; election-methods
 Subject: [EM] STV and single constraints, like gender quotas
 
 
 Dear all,
 
 do anyone of you know the best way to incorporate single 
 constraints into STV and proportional rankings from STV (see 
 for instance: http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/issue9/p5.htm)?
 For instance, the constraint can be that at least 1/3 of the 
 elected seats go to candidates of each gender. I found some 
 information in the links below, but I wonder if there are 
 better or more recent suggestions: 
 http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE9/P1.HTM
 http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/issue9/p5.htm
 
 Best regards
 Peter Zborník
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Proportional, Accountable, Local (PAL) representation: isn't this a big deal?

2011-10-29 Thread James Gilmour
Interesting, but not relevant to what Kristofer had actually written.  Finland 
uses a party-list voting system  -  Kristopher was
writing about STV, and specifically about 5-member districts.
James

-Original Message-
From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
[mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On Behalf Of Juho Laatu
Sent: Saturday, October 29, 2011 5:11 PM
To: EM
Subject: Re: [EM] Proportional, Accountable,Local (PAL) representation: isn't 
this a big deal?


On 29.10.2011, at 16.58, James Gilmour wrote:


Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Saturday, October 29, 2011 9:14 AM


STV is not mixed member proportional. As for the complexity issue, STV 


seems to work where it has been implemented. I agree that complexity 


will put a bound on how large each district can be, but as long as you 


keep below that size, it should work.



If you have a district size of 5 members and 10 parties, that would give 


a seemingly unmanagable number of 50 candidates.



I think that is most unlikely.  The only party that would likely nominate five 
candidates would be one that had reason to believe it
could win at least four of the five seats in the multi-member district.  
Parties that might have an expectation of winning two seats
would likely nominate only three candidates.  Parties that expected to win only 
one seat would nominate at most two candidates, and
based on our experience here in Scotland, many would nominate only one.

So the total number of candidates in a 5-member district would almost certainly 
be far short of 50I think a total of 20 would be
much more likely.



Here's some data from last parliamentary elections in Finland.

The largest multi-member district had 35 representatives and 405 candidates. 
All the large parties had 35 candidates. The largest
party got 11 representatives.

The two smallest multi-member districts had 6 representatives and 94 or 108 
candidates. 

One of the parties grew from 5 representatives to 39 representatives. So it 
needed lots of candidates too in order to not run out of
candidates in some districts.

(see http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Finnish_parliamentary_election,_2011)

If one has only one or two candidates more than the number of representatives 
that this party has or expects to get, then the
decision on who will be elected will be mainly made by the party and not by the 
voters. Preliminaries could help a bit by allowing
at least the party members to influence.

If proportional results are counted separately at each district, then it would 
be good to have a large number of representatives per
district to achieve accurate proportionality. In order to allow the voters to 
decide who will be elected there should be maybe twice
as many candidates per each party as that party will get representatives. In 
that way no seats are safe.

It is also good if there are such candidates that are not likely to be elected 
this time but that may gain popularity in these
elections and become elected in the next elections. All this sums up to quite a 
large number of candidates.

My favourite approach to implementing ranked style voting in this kind of 
environments would be to combine party affiliation and
rankings somehow. The idea is that even a bullet vote or a short ranked vote 
would be counted for the party by default. If one looks
this from the open list method point of view, this could mean just allowing the 
voter to rank few candidates instead of naming only
one. Already ability to rank three candidates would make party internal 
proportionality in open list methods much better. Probably
there is typically no very widespread need to rank candidates of different 
parties in this kind of elections, but it ok to support
also this if the method and the requirement of simplicity of voting do allow 
that. From STV point of view the problem is how to
allow better proportionality and voter decisions instead of party decisions in 
some nice way.

Juho





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] A design flaw in the electoral system

2011-10-03 Thread James Gilmour
Michael Allan   Sent: Monday, October 03, 2011 9:31 AM
 ABSTRACT
 
 An individual vote has no effect on the formal outcome of the 
 election; whether the vote is cast or not, the outcome is the 
 same regardless.

These statements worry me  -  surely they contain a logical flaw?  If these 
statements were true and every elector responded
rationally, no-one would ever vote.  Then the outcome would not be the same.

I am not into logic, but I suspect the flaw is in some disconnection between 
the individual and the aggregate.  When A with 100
votes wins over B with 99 votes, we cannot say which of the 100 individual 
votes for A was the winning vote, but it is clear that
is any one of those 100 votes had not been for A, then A would not have won.  
At best, if one A-voter had stayed at home, there
would have been a tie.  If one of the A-voters had voted for B instead, the 
outcome would have been very different.

Or am I missing something?

I do appreciate that there can be a disconnection, large or small, between the 
outcome of an election and the consequences in
government (policy implementation  -  or not), but the statements quoted above 
were specifically about elections per se.  That's why
I'm puzzled.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 87, Issue 54

2011-09-24 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, September 23, 2011 11:23 PM
 My point is, that the two examples you gave IMO are very 
 *strong* Condorcet winners in the sense that the vast 
 majority of voters would prefer the Condorcet winner over one 
 or the other of the other two candidates which are far less 
 popularly approved.

Yes, in YOUR opinion these were both strong Condorcet winners.  But I made it 
very clear  -  which you persistently ignore  -
that it was electors with a majoritarian view of elections and partisan 
politicians and party members who are likely to regard the
5% first preferences Condorcet winner as weak.  And I based that assessment 
on my experience of politics and elections in the UK,
with which I have been involved for 50 years.  Maybe my reading of the US and 
Canadian press is too selective, but I see much the
same attitudes expressed there  -  no surprise given that both share the 
appalling British legacy of plurality elections in
single-member districts.

 
 I think the IRV fanatics oppose centrist compromise winners 
 who are supported by a majority of voters whenever IRV would 
 elect a less popular winner. IRV proponents support a more 
 extremist winner, supported by far fewer voters as long as 
 the candidate, enough to fabricate hypothetical political 
 consequences, claiming that a majority people would oppose 
 the Condorcet winner.  Sure, of course at least a few persons 
 who had supported the 1st round plurality winner would 
 complain, but that is probably all.  I.e. IRV proponents seem 
 to be deeply emotionally attached to the method, regardless 
 of how much unhappiness the outcome would cause in how large 
 a proportion of voters by eliminating the Condorcet winner, 
 as it did in Burlington, VT.

My comments were in no way based on the views (or likely views) of any IRV 
fanatics.  I would certainly favour the election of
centrist compromise candidates, but I fear the election of a weak Condorcet 
winner (i.e. one with few first preferences) to a
position of real political power would immediately trigger a call to repeal the 
Condorcet reform and revert to the previous
plurality system.


 Burlington, VT is a real life counterexample to your 
 counterfactual, where people would have preferred the 
 Condorcet winner and so got rid of IRV.

So Burlington adopted the Condorcet system?  No, I thought not.  The failure to 
elect the Condorcet winner may have added some
theoretical fuel to the flames in the campaign to ditch IRV, but the real 
impetus came from those who wanted to go back to FPTP with
top-two run-off when the front-runner didn't achieve the artificial threshold.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 87, Issue 54

2011-09-24 Thread James Gilmour
Ralph Suter   Sent: Saturday, September 24, 2011 3:12 AM
 1. Despite your own certainty about how the real world of partisan 
 politics functions, your opinion is entirely speculative  with no basis 
 in historical events, since no Condorcet elections have ever been held 
 in any major public elections (or even any minor ones I am aware of).

You are right, so far as I am aware  -  there have never been any Condorcet 
public elections anywhere in the world.  That in itself
should tell us something as the Condorcet voting system has been known since 
1785.

We do, however, have some preferential vote elections in Scotland (local 
government).  Both in the multi-winner (3 or 4) elections
and in the single-winner by-elections the winners after the transfers of votes 
are commonly those who had most first preference
votes  -  that should be no surprise.  But when a lower placed candidate comes 
through on vote transfers to win a by-election, there
are always some howls from the anti-reform parties.  There is no great public 
outcry about this here because we do not directly
elect anyone into a really powerful single-person office.


 2. In arriving at your conclusions, you have neglected two critically 
 important considerations.
 
a. A so-called weak Condorcet winner could, immediately following 
 an election, make strong and possibly widely persuasive arguments that 
 she/he not only deserves to have won but is the strongest possible 
 winner, one who in separate contests with every other candidate would 
 defeat every one - or, in the event there was a cycle that had to be 
 resolved, would still have credible claim to be stronger overall than 
 any other candidate. She/he could then quickly move beyond such 
 arguments to act in ways that demonstrate her or his actual political 
 strength beyond any reasonable doubt. The early carpers about the 
 candidate being a weak winner would soon be forced to shift focus to 
 other more important issues. If you want to seriously address practical 
 politics, you need to address this highly credible 
 post-election scenario.

I follow your argument,  but I wonder how well a directly-elected President of 
the USA would be managing right now if that President
was a weak Condorcet winner, with say only 5% of the first preference votes in 
a 3-candidate contest.


b. Your arguments, weak though they are, are even less applicable (if 
 at all) to  elections of legislators than to elections of officials in 
 executive offices (president, mayor, etc). In fact, in a sharply divided 
 electorate (whether divided on ideological, religious, ethnic, or other 
 grounds), most people would likely prefer a middle-ground compromise 
 winner (even one from a small minority party or group) than one from the 
 major opposing party or group they strongly disliked, since the 
 middle-ground winner would, though far from ideal to most voters, also 
 make far less objectionable legislative decisions overall than a 
 stronger but widely disliked major party winner.

All legislators (federal House of Representatives, federal Senate, State 
legislatures, and city, town and county councils) should
all be elected by some system of proportional representation to ensure proper 
representation of the voters.  Discussion about weak
Condorcet winners should be of no relevance to such elections because none on 
the members of those representative assemblies
should be elected by single-winner voting systems.  Much more of political 
benefit could have been achieved if some of the
considerable effort expended on the near-insoluble problems of obtaining (and 
measuring) the best representation in single-winner
elections had been directed to that more practical objective.

James Gilmour


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 87, Issue 54

2011-09-24 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer MunsterhjelmSent: Saturday, September 24, 2011 10:22 PM
  James Gilmour wrote:
  You are right, so far as I am aware  -  there have never been any 
  Condorcet public elections anywhere in the world.  That in itself 
  should tell us something as the Condorcet voting system has 
  been known since 1785.
 
 Nanson's method was used in city elections in Marquette, Michigan. It 
 might not be a very large-scale public election, but I think 
 it was public.

Although Nanson's method satisfies the Condorcet criterion, I would not have 
recognised it as a Condorcet count.  It is essentially
a variation of the Borda points system.  To me, Condorcet counts are based 
strictly on pair-wise comparisons.  According to the
Wikipedia page, Nanson's method was used for those city elections in the 1920s 
(when other US cities were using STV) and for some
semi-public elections in Australia.  But if we regard Nanson's method as a 
Borda count, of course Borda counts have been and still
are used for some public elections.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Weak Condorcet winners

2011-09-23 Thread James Gilmour
Warren Smith   Sent: Friday, September 23, 2011 1:53 AM
 At the present time, Jon Huntsman gets only a tiny
 fraction of the USA-republican-presidential-nomination votes, 
 according to polls. For this reason, certain media people 
 have been saying it is a travesty Huntsman continues to run 
 and is allowed in debates, etc.
 
 However...
 it is mathematically possible (and might even be true -- I 
 have no idea... it's at least somewhat plausible) that 
 Huntsman is everybody's second choice and therefore is the 
 Condorcet candidate who would defeat every Republican rival 
 one on one.
 
 So there's a possible very important example of a weak 
 Condorcet winner in your face right now.

Your point is obscure.  My point is not that a weak Condorcet winner might 
exist or be elected, but about the political and
Political consequences of such a result.  The electors may vote that way, but 
once they and the party politicians see what has
happened all hell will break loose.  And it will be stirred up by a very 
hostile media.  At least, that's what I would confidently
predict would happen here in the UK.  The weak Condorcet winner, while being 
the Condorcet winner, would be totally ineffective in
the discharge of the office to which s/he was elected.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Weak Condorcet winners

2011-09-23 Thread James Gilmour
Juho   Sent: Friday, September 23, 2011 12:29 PM
 I think term weak CW should not be used as a general term 
 without referring to in what sense that winner is weak. There 
 are different elections and different needs. In some of them 
 weak CW is a good choice, in some others not.
 
 51: A
 49: B

Yes, this CW is weak in terms of difference from the opposition, but that weak 
winner will be accepted by the electorate who, in
countries like the UK, USA and Canada, take a majoritarian view.  And it will 
be accepted by the partisan politicians because next
time, it could be our turn.


 As you can see A is a weak CW here. Not so if you measure the 
 number of first preferences, but very much so if you compare 
 the strength of the winner to the strength of its competitors.
 
 45: ABC
 5: BAC
 5: BCA
 45: CBA

If this is an election, I don't think the Condorcet winner here, with only 10% 
of the first preferences, would be effective in
office in a country with an electorate of majoritarian view and partisan 
politicians and media to match.


But now you have introduced something completely different.  This next example 
is an exercise in choosing among policy options.  
 A = set tax level to 20%
 B = set tax level to 19%
 C = set tax level to 18%
 
 It is obvious that B is the alternative that should be 
 chosen. Other end results would be plain wrong. B is not a 
 weak candidate in any way.

Your are wrong to use the word candidate here.  This is not a candidate 
election  -  it is a decision about policy options.  And
that is something very different.  In my experience, the attitudes and 
approaches of electors (and even politicians) to these two
different tasks also differ.  What would be acceptable in making a policy 
decision (a weak Condorcet winner) would not be acceptable
in a candidate election.  This is a practical distinction the advocates of a 
social choice approach (sociology + political economy)
have failed to understand and appreciate.


 Term weak CW seems to be heavily linked to the 
 understanding that the winner should have lots of first 
 preference support

This is what electors, at least in some countries (UK, USA?, Canada?) clearly 
seem to be wanting and saying.  As I said in first
post under the original heading, I think we could sell the third-placed 
Condorcet winner provided that candidate was not too far
behind the front two in first preferences.  But the really weak CW, that is 
weak in first preference votes (5% or 10%), is not worth
thinking about in terms of practical reform of the voting system to be used for 
public elections in such countries.


 (or it should often belong to the most 
 preferred subgroup of the candidates). This is a viewpoint 
 that is quite strong in two-party countries (that want to 
 stay as two-party countries) since in those countries whoever 
 is in charge has typically more than 50% support among the 
 voters.

No, that is typical only of the USA (a very atypical example of FPTP)  -  it is 
not typical of the UK or Canada.  NO government in
the UK since 1945 has been elected with even 50% of the votes, never mind more 
than 50% support among the voters.  But with two
exceptions, all of those governments had absolute majorities of seats in the 
Parliament.

I am not sure how you define two-party countries, but for several decades the 
UK has had three significant parties and Scotland
and Wales have each had four significant parties.  And the majoritarian view of 
single-winner elections prevails.


 But what is weak in this kind of thinking need not be 
 weak in some other set-up.

But what matters here is the perception of the electors  -  and how the 
partisan politicians (and hostile media) could exploit that
to render a weak Condorcet winner ineffective in office.
 

  Failing the majority criterion is, in my view, a similar flaw to 
  electing a weak CW.
 
 I think electing a weak CW is a flaw only in some set-ups 
 with some specific requirements that make weak CW a bad 
 choice. Majority criterion is a requirement far more often, 
 but not always. There are also elections where majority is 
 not a requirement. And there are also elections where it is 
 sometimes a requirement to elect against the majority opinion.

This sounds more like (benign) dictatorship than democratic representation.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 87, Issue 54

2011-09-23 Thread James Gilmour
But you are completely missing the point of what I wrote.  It is the political 
consequences of the second result that are important.

In the real world of partisan politics, such a weak Condorcet winner (and their 
policies) would likely be torn to shreds by the
party politicians and their party members, to such an extent that s/he would be 
ineffectual in office.  And based on my experience
of UK electors, with their majoritarian views of elections, the weak Condorcet 
winner would get little support from those whose
votes had voted him or her into office.  It must be for others to judge whether 
the electors in their countries (USA, Canada) would
react in a similar way, but I have seen nothing in the US or Canadian press to 
suggest otherwise.

It is dirty practical politics that is the problem here, not the fact that 
voters could rank their choices honestly.  In my view,
such a result would be less acceptable to the electors than the plurality 
result, despite all the obvious defects in the plurality
voting.  That's just how it is  -  and if you want to achieve real, practical 
reform, you have to understand that.

James Gilmour


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Friday, September 23, 2011 8:48 PM
 To: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Subject: Re: [EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 87, Issue 54
 
 
 In both the following cases, candidate C, the Condorcet 
 winner, is a GREAT choice because a majority of voters, in 
 both cases, would prefer C over A or B.  This system allows 
 voters to honestly rank their choices, without worrying about 
 helping their least favorite candidate to win - far better 
 than methods like IRV or plurality.
 
 35 AC
 34 BC
 31 C
 
 
 48 AC
 47 BC
  5 C
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Jameson Quinn   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 2:00 AM
 If I'm right, the claim is that voters, and especially 
 politicians, are intuitively concerned with the possibility 
 of someone winning with broad but shallow support. In 
 Approval, Condorcet, Majority Judgment, or Range, a 
 relatively-unknown centrist could theoretically win a contest 
 against two high-profile ideologically-opposed candidates. 
 The theory is that the electorate would be so polarized that 
 everyone would explicitly prefer the centrist to the other 
 extreme, but because the voters don't really expect the 
 low-profile centrist to win, they might miss some important 
 flaw in the centrist which actually makes her a poor winner.

I cannot comment on the quoted remark (cut) that prompted your post and I know 
nothing at all about the activities of anyone at
FairVote, but you have hit on a real problem in practical politics in your 
comment above  -  the problem of the weak Condorcet
winner.  This is a very real political problem, in terms of selling the voting 
system to partisan politicians (who are opposed to
any reform) and to a sceptical public.

For example, with 3 candidates and 100 voters (ignoring irritant preferences) 
we could have:
35 AC
34 BC
31 C
C is the Condorcet winner.  Despite the inevitable howls from FPTP 
supporters, I think we could sell such an outcome to the
electors.

But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
48 AC
47 BC
 5 C
C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I doubt 
whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the
electorate, at least, not here in the UK.

And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in office. 
Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the
politicians of Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder 
daily.  And the media would be no help  -  they would
just pour fuel on the flames.  The result would be political chaos and totally 
ineffective government.

The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet winner.  
But IRV avoids the political problem of the weak
Condorcet winner.  I suspect that's why IRV has been accepted for many public 
and semi-public elections despite the Condorcet flaw.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Peter Zbornik  Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 6:41 PM
 I agree with James, and that was why I proposed that election 
 reform took the path through added election rounds.
 
 Reform of FPTP would thus add a second election round where 
 the Condorcet winner would meet the FPTP winner. Who in the 
 UK would object to that?

I cannot think of ANYONE in the UK who would support a proposal for any form of 
two-round voting for public elections.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 7:00 PM
  On 9/22/11 12:40 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
  But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant 
 preferences):
  48 AC
  47 BC
   5 C
  C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I
  doubt whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the 
  electorate, at least, not here in the UK.
 
 even though there were 48 voters who preferred C over B, 47 that 
 preferred C over A, along with the 5 that preferred C over 
 both A and B.
 
 that does not appear to me to be such a bad result.

But you are missing the point.  It is not how the Condorcet winner appears to 
you or to me  -  it is how that winner, with only 5%
of the first preferences, is seen by ordinary electors and by hostile partisan 
politicians of Party A and Party B.  I think I know
how that result would be received in the UK (total rejection), and I would 
expect a similar reaction in the USA or Canada, judging
by what I have read in their on-line newspapers.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Weak Condorcet winners [was: FairVote are not the friendliest]

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Jameson Quinn   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 7:38 PM
 And while I don't take everything Richie says at face value, 
 he does have more experience than basically anyone else at 
 promoting voting reform, so it would be unwise to entirely 
 ignore his point of view. I believe that he honestly sees the 
 weak Condorcet winner scenario as an impediment to promoting 
 Condorcet, and one of his basic reasons for putting his eggs 
 in the IRV basket. So I think the scenario does deserve 
 attention. And not just from the point of view of actually 
 resolving the issue, but also from the point of view of 
 finding a sound bite/talking point for overcoming it.

I have been actively involved in practical electoral reform in the UK for fifty 
(50) years and never in all that time have I heard
anyone suggest the use of a Condorcet system.  IRV (and STV-PR) have been under 
practical consideration and promotion (and nearly
adopted) in the UK since the late 1880s.

I suspect Condorcet didn't get a look-in because, compared with IRV, it gets 
progressively more complicated with each increase of
candidates above three and because there was no agreed and SIMPLE means of 
breaking Condorcet cycles (and there still isn't).   I
suspect the specific issue of the weak Condorcet winner may not then have 
been too significant because no-one suggested using a
Condorcet system.  But that would certainly be an issue now, given the nature 
of our current politics.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] [CES #3650] FairVote folks are not the friendliest bunch

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Toby PereiraSent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 8:11 PM
  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
 But suppose the votes had been (again ignoring irrelevant preferences):
48 AC
 47 BC
 5 C
  C is still the Condorcet winner - no question about that.  But I 
 doubt whether anyone could successfully sell such a result to the 
 electorate, at least, not here in the UK.
 
 And I have severe doubts about how effective such a winner could be in 
 office. Quite apart from the sceptical electorate, the politicians of 
 Party A and of Party B would be hounding such an office-holder daily.  
 And the media would be no help  -  they would just pour fuel on the 
 flames.  The result would be political chaos and totally ineffective 
 government.
 
 The flaw in IRV is that it can, sometimes, fail to elect the Condorcet 
 winner.  But IRV avoids the political problem of the weak Condorcet 
 winner.  I suspect that's why IRV has been accepted for many public and 
 semi-public elections despite the Condorcet flaw.

 I don't think I would have a problem with C winning here, if 
 the votes were all sincere.

Even if all the votes are sincere, it is irrelevant what you or I think.  It is 
what ordinary electors would think about such a
winner, with only 5% of the first preferences.  And those electors would not be 
left in peace to reflect quietly on the potential of
their (weak) Condorcet winner.  Their views would be whipped up by partisan 
politicians and by a hostile press and media.  That
Condorcet winner would still be the Condorcet winner, but that's not how such 
an outcome would be portrayed.  The world of real
politics is a very brutal, nasty and dirty place, but that's where practical 
electoral reformers have to work (at least for the time
being) if they really want to change anything.

James Gilmour





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Weak Condorcet winners [was: FairVote are not thefriendliest]

2011-09-22 Thread James Gilmour
Peter Zbornik   Sent: Thursday, September 22, 2011 9:04 PM
 Well I think the argument that two-rounds systems are silly 
 and complex, can be countered with the fact that it is used 
 all throughout Europe and elsewhere.

Yes, and the French Presidential election of 2002 showed us very clearly what 
is wrong with such two-round voting systems.


 I would say runoff 
 elections are the standard way of conducting single member  
 elections. Even though I have no data for this claim,

Yes, I should like to see some hard data to back up that statement.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Preferential Party List Method Proposal

2011-08-14 Thread James Gilmour
Greg Nisbet   Sent: Sunday, August 14, 2011 4:31 AM
My system does not have voters voting for candidates at all. In fact, 
candidates needn't even exist (theoretically of course) for my
method to be well-defined. Instead people simply vote for parties, with parties 
that can't get any seats dropped from the lowest
weight first. Making the system more candidate-centric could be done, but my 
algorithm (or class of algorithms) is supposed to be a
minimal, easily analyzable change from non-preferential party list methods.  
 
But this is not what the majority of electors want, at least not in polities 
like USA, Canada and UK.  Electors in some continental
European countries do seem to be happy with party list PR without any voter 
choice of candidates, but I would suggest, that would
not be acceptable in our political culture.   For the UK, that opinion is based 
on various public opinion polls; for the USA and
Canada it is based on my reading of local media and blogs.
 
James Gilmour
 
 

Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Preferential Party List Method Proposal

2011-08-13 Thread James Gilmour
Greg Nisbet   Sent: Saturday, August 13, 2011 10:25 PM
 All current forms of party list proportional representation 
 have each voter cast a vote for a single party. I say this is 
 inadequate since a small party can be eliminated and hence 
 denied any representation (this is particularly relevant if 
 the legislature has a threshold). However, votes for a party 
 that doesn't have sufficient support to win any seats in the 
 legislature are simply wasted.

Not necessarily so.  See apparentement.  Parties can chain their votes so 
that fewer votes are wasted in the seat allocation
calculations.

James Gilmour


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info



Re: [EM] Record activity on the EM list?

2011-08-06 Thread James Gilmour
 Juho Laatu   Sent: Thursday, August 04, 2011 5:12 PM
  On 4.8.2011, at 14.21, James Gilmour wrote:
  There is only one real issue in elections: representation of the 
  voters.
  
  If in a single winner partisan election the voters vote 51% for A and 
  49% for B, we have a major problem in representation.
 
 Ok, 49% of the voters without representation.

This throws the problem into its sharpest perspective.  There are related, 
difficult problems when there are three, four or more
candidates for the one seat.


 If one uses single-member districts to elect multiple 
 representatives, then this means also some randomness in the 
 results. This is not really a problem of single-winner 
 methods themselves but a problem in how they are used (as 
 multi-winner methods).

I agree.  It is fundamentally wrong to use any single-winner, single-member 
district voting system to elect the members of a
representative assembly (e.g. city council, state legislature).


  But if the voters vote in the same way (51% to 49%) in a two-member 
  election, any sensible voting system will give one seat to A and one 
  seat to B.
  
  Compared to that difference in providing representation of the 
  voters, all the other differences between single-winner and 
  multi-winner elections are trivial.
 
 From this point of view single-winner methods are more 
 problematic than multi-winner methods (at least when used 
 to elect multiple representatives from single-member 
 districts).

No  -  not just when (improperly) used to elect the members of a 
representative assembly.  THE problem is inherent in the
single-winner election.   As you go on to say in your next comment.

 This problem of single-winner methods is quite 
 impossible to fix (most single-winner methods respect the 
 will of the majority).

The extreme problem (51% to 49%) is impossible to fix and so it is the greatest 
challenge in electoral science to obtain the most
representative outcome.  In the two-candidate election, the best we can do is 
to guarantee representation to the majority.

 
 The 51% vs. 49% problem is present also in accurately 
 proportional representative bodies since also those bodies 
 may make majority decisions. One way to alleviate this kind 
 of narrow majority related problems is to seek compromise 
 decisions.

I have to part company with you here.  It should NOT, in my view, be part of 
the function of the voting system to manipulate the
votes to obtain any outcome other than representation of the voters.  It is 
not part of the function of a voting system to seek
consensus.

If the voters want to vote for candidates who will seek consensus, that's fine  
-  but that is very different for making seek
consensus an objective of the voting system.

The function of the voting system should simply be to return the most 
representative result in terms of representing the voters,
as expressed by the voters' responses to the candidates who have offered 
themselves for election.

Seeking consensus and not seeking consensus are aspects of how the elected 
members will behave within the elected assembly.  And
of course, the voters may rightly take such views into account in their 
assessments of the candidates before they cast their votes.
But that is just part of candidate appraisal.  Given a sensitive voting system, 
the outcome (seats won) will reflect the views of
the voters, which may include views on seeking consensus.

James


 That is what in principle happens e.g. in 
 coalition governments. Coalition governments may represent 
 well over 50% of the voters. Let's assume that this is the 
 case. The program of the government may contain multiple 
 topics that would be 51% vs. 49% questions in the 
 representative body or among the voters, but probably all 
 coalition members will get more than they lose. Let's assume 
 that the coalition is heterogeneous so that it does not agree 
 on all the 51% vs. 49% decisions that is has to make. Maybe 
 there are two 51% vs. 49% topics that go the right way 
 against every one such topic that goes wrong. In that way we 
 don't have a narrow majority that always makes 51% decisions 
 but a supermajority that has considerably higher support behind
   everything it does (although all parties of the coalition 
 do not like all the decisions).
 
 In two-party systems the balance is based more on two 
 alternating policies. Often both parties have quite centrist 
 policies since both try to meet the needs of the median 
 voters. In some topics they may however have also clearly 
 opposite positions. I guess the overall policy and results of 
 two-party system governments are typically more 51% majority 
 driven than in multi-party governments. (Coalition 
 governments may however also have only narrow majority and 
 the coalitions may be quite fixed, e.g. left vs. right, and 
 as a result their decisions may follow the 51% majority style.)
 
 My point is just that in addition to multi-winner methods

Re: [EM] Record activity on the EM list?

2011-08-06 Thread James Gilmour
You can also have minority government (usually single-party), where the 
majorities are by consensus, issue by issue, transcending
the parties.

Incidentally, what is pure proportional representation?  It is a term I have 
come across quite frequently.

James


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Juho Laatu
 Sent: Saturday, August 06, 2011 5:38 PM
 To: EM list
 Subject: Re: [EM] Record activity on the EM list?
 
 
 I was also looking for pure proportional representation. The 
 compromise decisions would take place after the election in a 
 representative body or in a government. The election methods 
 need not be tampered. My theory was just that in the case 
 that the majority (of parties) that forms the government is 
 considerably larger than 51% the decisions could have wider 
 support than in the typical 51+% governments of a two-party 
 system. The larger government would have to make compromises 
 that are at least acceptable to all parties in the government.
 
 Juho
 
 
 On 6.8.2011, at 17.39, James Gilmour wrote:
 
  Juho Laatu   Sent: Thursday, August 04, 2011 5:12 PM
  On 4.8.2011, at 14.21, James Gilmour wrote:
  There is only one real issue in elections: representation of the
  voters.
  
  If in a single winner partisan election the voters vote 51% for A 
  and
  49% for B, we have a major problem in representation.
  
  Ok, 49% of the voters without representation.
  
  This throws the problem into its sharpest perspective.  There are 
  related, difficult problems when there are three, four or more 
  candidates for the one seat.
  
  
  If one uses single-member districts to elect multiple
  representatives, then this means also some randomness in the 
  results. This is not really a problem of single-winner 
  methods themselves but a problem in how they are used (as 
  multi-winner methods).
  
  I agree.  It is fundamentally wrong to use any single-winner, 
  single-member district voting system to elect the members of a 
  representative assembly (e.g. city council, state legislature).
  
  
  But if the voters vote in the same way (51% to 49%) in a 
 two-member
  election, any sensible voting system will give one seat 
 to A and one 
  seat to B.
  
  Compared to that difference in providing representation of the
  voters, all the other differences between single-winner and 
  multi-winner elections are trivial.
  
  From this point of view single-winner methods are more
  problematic than multi-winner methods (at least when used 
  to elect multiple representatives from single-member 
  districts).
  
  No  -  not just when (improperly) used to elect the members 
 of a representative assembly.  THE problem is inherent in the
  single-winner election.   As you go on to say in your next comment.
  
  This problem of single-winner methods is quite
  impossible to fix (most single-winner methods respect the 
  will of the majority).
  
  The extreme problem (51% to 49%) is impossible to fix and 
 so it is the 
  greatest challenge in electoral science to obtain the most 
  representative outcome.  In the two-candidate election, 
 the best we 
  can do is to guarantee representation to the majority.
  
  
  The 51% vs. 49% problem is present also in accurately
  proportional representative bodies since also those bodies 
  may make majority decisions. One way to alleviate this kind 
  of narrow majority related problems is to seek compromise 
  decisions.
  
  I have to part company with you here.  It should NOT, in my 
 view, be 
  part of the function of the voting system to manipulate the 
 votes to 
  obtain any outcome other than representation of the 
 voters.  It is 
  not part of the function of a voting system to seek consensus.
  
  If the voters want to vote for candidates who will seek consensus, 
  that's fine  -  but that is very different for making seek 
 consensus 
  an objective of the voting system.
  
  The function of the voting system should simply be to 
 return the most 
  representative result in terms of representing the voters, as 
  expressed by the voters' responses to the candidates who 
 have offered 
  themselves for election.
  
  Seeking consensus and not seeking consensus are aspects 
 of how the 
  elected members will behave within the elected assembly.  And of 
  course, the voters may rightly take such views into account 
 in their 
  assessments of the candidates before they cast their votes. 
 But that 
  is just part of candidate appraisal.  Given a sensitive 
 voting system, 
  the outcome (seats won) will reflect the views of the voters, which 
  may include views on seeking consensus.
  
  James
  
  
  That is what in principle happens e.g. in
  coalition governments. Coalition governments may represent 
  well over 50% of the voters. Let's assume that this is the 
  case. The program of the government may contain multiple

Re: [EM] Record activity on the EM list?

2011-08-04 Thread James Gilmour
There is only one real issue in elections: representation of the voters.

If in a single winner partisan election the voters vote 51% for A and 49% for 
B, we have a major problem in representation.

But if the voters vote in the same way (51% to 49%) in a two-member election, 
any sensible voting system will give one seat to A and
one seat to B.

Compared to that difference in providing representation of the voters, all 
the other differences between single-winner and
multi-winner elections are trivial.

James

 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Juho Laatu
 Sent: Thursday, August 04, 2011 7:07 AM
 To: EM list
 Subject: Re: [EM] Record activity on the EM list?
 
 
 Yes, there are areas where single-winner methods are more 
 challenging. For example multi-winner STV works better than 
 single-winner STV, and it is easier to collect sincere 
 ratings in multi-winner methods than in single-winner 
 methods. On the other hand the field of study may be wider in 
 multi-winenr methods (a bit like N is more complicated than 
 1). In multi-winner methods we may have some additional 
 aspects to study and solve like proportionality, geographical 
 proportionality and the computational complexity related 
 problems tend to cause problems. Individual problems may thus 
 be more numerous in multi-winner methods although some 
 individual problems may be more challenging in single-winner methods.
 
 Juho
 
 
 
 On 3.8.2011, at 19.35, James Gilmour wrote:
 
  Juho Laatu   Sent: Wednesday, August 03, 2011 6:04 AM
  Multi-winner methods are, if possible, even more complicated
  than single-winner methods. 
  
  I disagree.  It is much easier to obtain a satisfactory 
  (representative, acceptable) outcome for a multi-winner 
 election than 
  it is to obtain a satisfactory (representative, 
 acceptable) outcome 
  for a single-winner election.  Choosing a method to elect the 
  candidate who best represents the voters in a single-winner 
 election 
  is the most difficult challenge in electoral science.  As 
 soon as you 
  elect two or more candidates together, many of the problems 
 disappear.
  
  James Gilmour
  
  
  
  Election-Methods mailing list - see 
 http://electorama.com/em for list 
  info
 
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Record activity on the EM list?

2011-08-03 Thread James Gilmour
Juho Laatu   Sent: Wednesday, August 03, 2011 6:04 AM
 Multi-winner methods are, if possible, even more complicated 
 than single-winner methods. 

I disagree.  It is much easier to obtain a satisfactory (representative, 
acceptable) outcome for a multi-winner election than it
is to obtain a satisfactory (representative, acceptable) outcome for a 
single-winner election.  Choosing a method to elect the
candidate who best represents the voters in a single-winner election is the 
most difficult challenge in electoral science.  As soon
as you elect two or more candidates together, many of the problems disappear.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Challenge: two-party methods

2011-07-09 Thread James Gilmour
Juho Laatu   Sent: Saturday, July 09, 2011 10:35 AM
 After some recent discussions and thoughts around two-party 
 systems I thought it would be interesting to discuss 
 two-party systems also in a more positive spirit. The 
 assumption is thus that we want the system to be two-party 
 oriented. We want to have two strong parties, and one of them 
 should rule. We want to allow only well established parties 
 with wide support to rule. The first obvious approach is to 
 ban all other parties than the two leading parties. But maybe 
 we don't want  to be so brutal. Let's not ban the possibly 
 already existing, much liked and hopeful third parties. It is 
 also good to have some competition in the system. Let's not 
 allow the two leading parties think that they don't have to 
 care about the voters and they can do whatever they want, and 
 stay in power forever.

This is a very strange proposal, all the more so because your principal 
objective is not clear.  Is your objective to manipulate the
voting system so that all the smaller parties are more or less crushed out of 
the political system, leaving only two?  Or is your
objective to ensure single-party majority government where the government comes 
directly from the national elections?

The first of these is not, to my mind, compatible with any definition of 
democracy.

If single-party majority government is the objective, that is very easy to 
implement.  If no party (in fairly representative
elections) wins more than half of the seats, allocate 55% of the seats to the 
party with most votes nationally and divide the
remaining seats proportionately among the remaining parties.  This has already 
been done in national public elections, e.g. in Italy
in the 1920s, when the 'premium' was two-thirds not 55%.

Assuming you are suggesting this in the context of electing an assembly 
(national or regional parliament) and not a single-winner
election (state governor or president), it is very interesting to note what 
happened in Malta after STV-PR was introduced some 80
years ago.  Before STV-PR was introduced AND for the first 40 years of its use, 
candidates from three, four or five parties were
elected to the Parliament at each election, but for the past 40 years only two 
parties have been represented in the Parliament.  If
you believe at all in representative democracy I think it is much the best to 
leave that aspect of party dynamics to the voters.

James



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Challenge: two-party methods

2011-07-09 Thread James Gilmour
Juho
I regret to have to say that I find your approach confused and confusing, and 
basically anti-democratic  -  which is a surprise and
a disappointment.

There is nothing at all wrong with a two party system if that is what the 
voters really want.  But it is something else altogether
to devise or manipulate a voting system so that it will produce a two party 
result when that is not the wish of the voters.  There
is nothing inherently good or bad about a two party system, provided it does 
fairly reflect the wishes of the voters.  Of course,
such a system would be bad if it did not fairly reflect the wishes of the 
voters.

If we are discussing voting systems for use within a representative democracy 
to elect a parliament or assembly, I cannot see how
there can be any escape from the requirement for democracy in the voting 
system.  A voting system may have one effect or another,
and its effects may be tolerated by the electors, but that is quite different 
from deliberately devising a system to crush the
smaller parties.  That can only be anti-democratic.

All political parties are coalitions, some broad, some narrow.  So there is a 
very simple solution to the spoiler problem where
single-party majority government is required, especially with the 55% seats 
rule for the largest minority.  If the potentially
largest party finds itself second, all it has to do is broaden its internal 
coalition to take in the supporters of the most
acceptable of the spoiler parties so that it will secure first place.  The 
attraction for the spoiler party is that it will become
part of the government.

One could argue that plurality in single-member districts, as in the UK and the 
USA, is a voting system designed for a two party
political system (ignoring its other defects).  Conservative and Labour in the 
UK and Republicans and Democrats in the USA no doubt
see this system as a mechanism for entrenching and reinforcing the two party 
system.  It is thus interesting, that in England there
is a three party system and in Scotland a four party system, and these emerged 
under plurality in SMDs.  What happened in these two
countries, for different reasons, was that the two main parties were not able 
to broaden their coalitions and successfully reach out
to the third and fourth parties and the supporters of the third and fourth 
parties.  It is my view that in England, at least, the
political landscape could have been quite different if the UK had used STV-PR 
to elect the Westminster Parliament since 1945.

On a smaller point, I find your use of single winner undesirably confusing.  
Surely single-winner should refer only to
single-seat elections?  The term has to mean something very different if you 
try to apply it to multi-seat elections for a
representative assembly.  In a single-seat election the best you can do is 
guarantee representation to the majority of those
participating in the vote  -  and you deny any representation to all the 
minorities.  But in a multi-seat election the situation can
be, and should be, completely different, in that you can guarantee 
representation to all significant points of view.  So I think we
should always reserve single-winner for single-seat elections and use 
single-party majority for multi-seat elections.  The
concepts are quite different.

James



Juho Laatu   Sent: Saturday, July 09, 2011 2:53 PM
 
  On 9.7.2011, at 16.14, James Gilmour wrote:
  Juho Laatu   Sent: Saturday, July 09, 2011 10:35 AM
  After some recent discussions and thoughts around two-party
  systems I thought it would be interesting to discuss 
  two-party systems also in a more positive spirit. The 
  assumption is thus that we want the system to be two-party 
  oriented. We want to have two strong parties, and one of them 
  should rule. We want to allow only well established parties 
  with wide support to rule. The first obvious approach is to 
  ban all other parties than the two leading parties. But maybe 
  we don't want  to be so brutal. Let's not ban the possibly 
  already existing, much liked and hopeful third parties. It is 
  also good to have some competition in the system. Let's not 
  allow the two leading parties think that they don't have to 
  care about the voters and they can do whatever they want, and 
  stay in power forever.
  
  This is a very strange proposal, all the more so because your 
  principal objective is not clear.  Is your objective to manipulate the 
  voting system so that all the smaller parties are more or  less crushed 
  out of the political system, leaving only two?
 
 The idea is not to manipulate a working system but to provide 
 an ideal two-party system. The rules and ideals of a 
 two-party system may be different from other systems, so the 
 method may seem strange if seen as a proposal for some other 
 kind of elections (e.g. for multi-party countries). There may 
 thus be different elections with different kind of 
 requirements. Here the requirement

Re: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?

2011-07-05 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Tuesday, July 05, 2011 2:30 AM
 
  On Mon, Jul 4, 2011 at 7:19 PM, James Gilmour 
 
  Kathy, your comments illustrate the fundamental problems with all 
  party list voting systems: 1. you must have registered political 
  parties;
 
 As someone else noted in this thread already, registered 
 political parties are unnecessary to use the party list 
 system.  Candidates can simply put together their own lists.

But someone has to control, or take responsibility for, each list, even if it 
is only to submit it to the Returning Officer on
nomination day so that an agreed list will be printed on the ballot paper.  I 
am aware that in some jurisdictions otherwise
independent candidates can form groups for this purpose, but these groups 
are registered for the purpose of the election.


  2. each party must produce a list of candidates ordered in some way;
 
 Each *list* is normally ordered - Yes.  But the list method 
 does not have to be done that way if it is an open list 
 system where voters can vote for candidates, and thus voters 
 determine the list order.  

In open-list systems the names of the candidates are printed on the ballot 
paper, under the respective party headings.  So the names
must be ordered in some way, even if it is alphabetical or random.  So the 
voters do NOT determine the order of the candidates in
each party's list.  The voters may vote in ways that determine which of the 
listed candidates is elected to one of that party's
seats, and determine the order in which the candidates in a list are elected, 
but that is all post-election.  The voters in the
public election do not in any way determine the order of the candidates in the 
parties' lists as those names appear on the printed
ballot papers.


 Most voters would disagree with 
 you and think it is a benefit to have the political party or 
 leading candidate put together the list order for them so as 
 to save the voters the time and effort it would take to 
 research all the candidates.

It is clearly most voters in some countries (because those voters appear 
happy with their present closed-lists), but others would
disagree and prefer to have some or a lot of choice in determining which of 
their favoured party's candidates should actually fill
the seats allocated to that party.  The voters could have a great deal of 
effect without having to research every candidate or
indicate a ranking for every candidate on their favoured party's list.


  However, a less popular system, 
 would simply require voters to pick a candidate from the 
 list. 

I don't know what you mean by less popular, but this (pick one candidate) is 
in fact a common version of open-list party-list.


 I suppose it's possible, as some have also commented 
 here, to allow voters to rank order a list, but that would be 
 administratively burdensome and probably not practical for 
 large national elections, as has been mentioned.

The practicality depends on the size of the electoral districts, and on how the 
candidates are presented.  In some countries there
is one national list for each party; in others, the votes are totally 
nationally, but the parties' list are presented on a regional
basis.


  3. voters are restricted (to a greater or lesser
  degree) in how they can respond to the choices of representative 
  offered to them.
 
 Relative to some electoral methods that are less desirable in 
 other ways, perhaps.  However, the list system has many 
 benefits those other systems don't have, which is why it is 
 so popular in many countries - for nationwide legislative 
 bodies where other systems may not be practical or desirable.

Yes, even closed-list party-list delivers party PR in a way that some other 
systems do not, notably plurality in single-member
districts (UK, USA and Canada).  If there were no alternative, that would be an 
advance.  But we already know how to do better than
that.


  All of these impose unnecessary limitations on
  the PR of the voters that could be obtained by a less constrained 
  voting system.
 
 You might want to read up on the many studies of voting 
 behaviour - say American Voter Revisited or Controversies in 
 Voting Behavior. Most voters do not want to have to 
 investigate and individually rank hundreds of candidates, so 
 an open party list system where they are familiar with the 
 top ranked candidates on each list and have the chance to 
 vote for someone they prefer most to move them up the list.

I am certainly not recommending any voting system that would require voters to 
investigate and individually rank hundreds of
candidates.  That is both undesirable and unnecessary.  The number of 
candidates presented to voters in any one electoral district
is a function of electoral district size.

If the voter chooses a list headed by a familiar candidate and then has the 
chance to vote for someone they prefer most, it MAY
move that candidate up the list, but very large numbers of such votes

Re: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?

2011-07-04 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Monday, July 04, 2011 2:53 PM
  However, either the election method used within each party to 
  determine the list orders would be majoritarian (in which case the 
  system isn't proportional beyond the party level),
 
 Plurality is how it is done I believe.  To have PR within the 
 party would require some sort of party primary system I 
 suppose to determine which candidates are on each list in the 
 general election for each party.

This suggestion misses the point.  For any voting system to give full effect to 
proportional representation of the voters, the
selection of the candidates to take the seats won by a party must be decided by 
those who vote in the actual public election  -  not
decided by any kind of party primary.  After all, the party primary (before the 
public election) has already decided who should be
on the party's list and has ordered that list.

 The nice feature of existing party list methods is that it 
 allows the election of a large number of candidates to a 
 large national body of legislators without requiring voters 
 to rank individually a huge number of candidates. This makes 
 the job for voters and election administrators much easier 
 than asking voters to rank from among a huge number of 
 candidates.

But it is precisely this nice feature of most open-list party-list systems 
that causes the failure of such systems to produce
proportionality WITHIN parties.

If you are going to do this properly, to produce a within-party PR result, the 
voters for each party would have to mark preferences
against the candidates in their chosen party's list (not necessarily all 
candidates, depending on the system you choose).  And then
you would need to use STV-PR (or something like it as you don't like STV) to 
determine which candidates should take the seats
allocated to each party.  No such system could be precinct-summable, but that 
is not a priority for everyone.

And as has already been said, if you are prepared to go the bother of counting 
what is in effect a separate PR election WITHIN each
party, why not go all the way and apply your chosen PR system to all candidates 
across all parties?  That would give the voters real
choice and would also avoid completely the problem of entrenching the political 
power of the parties' machines.

James Gilmour



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?

2011-07-04 Thread James Gilmour
Juho Laatu   Sent: Monday, July 04, 2011 4:30 PM
 (Of course the idea of having proportionally ordered 
 candidate lists in a closer list election would make voting 
 in the actual election even simpler. But then one would need 
 to have a primary to find the ordering for each party.)

But that would not give proportional representation of the voters, i.e. those 
who voted in the public election.  Any ordering of a
party's list by a primary election can, at best, reflect only the views of 
those entitled to vote in that primary.  That is a
private, internal matter for each party. For real proportional representation 
of the VOTERS, the voters must be free to express
their opinions among the parties and among the candidates within the parties.  
That can be done only in the actual public election,
i.e. all at one time, when all the voters know which parties are contesting the 
election and can see all the candidates of all the
parties.

James


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?

2011-07-04 Thread James Gilmour
Jameson Quinn  Sent: Monday, July 04, 2011 5:03 PM
 As I said in my last message, asset-like systems can let you 
 have your cake and eat it, if you trust your favorite 
 candidate to agree with you in ranking other candidates. This 
 is fundamentally different from trusting your party, because 
 your favorite candidate in asset-like systems could, in 
 principle, be arbitrarily close to you - even BE you, if 
 you're willing to give up vote anonymity, and if the system 
 allows this extreme. Most systems will put some limits on 
 this, but still, they are far closer to this extreme than any 
 party list system. Also, there is no need to stay within the 
 arbitrary bounds of any party; a candidate can have 
 affinities based on ideology, so candidates at the fringes of 
 their party (including the centrist fringes) have full freedom.

I am a campaigner for practical reform of voting systems and I do not think an 
asset system or asset-like system will be acceptable
for partisan public elections  -  certainly not here in the UK.  And I see 
nothing in US or Canadian politics to make me think such
a system might be any more acceptable there.  


 I disagree about the no such system statement. I myself 
 have worked out an unpublished system which is not perfectly 
 droop-PR, but is a ~99% approximation thereof; and which is 
 complicated, but still 2n² summable. It's not worth sharing 
 the details here, but, having gone through the exercise, I 
 believe that it should be possible to do better than I did.

If you have done this I would encourage you to write it up for publication in 
the (somewhat informal) technical journal Voting
matters.  In the UK we do not sum or count the ballot papers from any public 
elections in the precincts, but it would be very
interesting to see how this could be done in a practical way for STV-PR or a 
system that would deliver comparable PR results.

James



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?

2011-07-04 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Monday, July 04, 2011 10:40 PM
 James,  As someone on this list already pointed out, such a 
 system as you suggest does *nothing* to ensure 
 proportionality *within* the party list because the list of 
 candidates could all have been chosen by either the leaders 
 or the majority of the political party prior to the election 
 and thus represent the same group within the party. 
 Therefore, I said that a party primary allowing all party 
 members to vote in a PR way would be needed *before* the 
 election in order to ensure proportionality. Unless, you are 
 suggesting a rule about how parties can operate requiring 
 that anyone can get on any party's ballot who wants to, or 
 has some number of signatures, without having permission of 
 the political party, I suppose.  Not sure what effects that 
 might have.  Thus, the suggestion for a party primary to 
 ensure proportionality among voting party members in the 
 primary, at least.

Kathy, your comments illustrate the fundamental problems with all party list 
voting systems: 1. you must have registered political
parties;  2. each party must produce a list of candidates ordered in some way;  
3. voters are restricted (to a greater or lesser
degree) in how they can respond to the choices of representative offered to 
them.  All of these impose unnecessary limitations on
the PR of the voters that could be obtained by a less constrained voting 
system.  I would also say that these restrictions are
undesirable, but that view reflects my political culture.  I do, however, 
recognise that these restrictions are accepted by many in
continental Europe who happily use party-list PR voting systems without any 
clamour for change.

Your comments also confuse what are essentially private matters with public 
matters.  The candidates who can stand in the name of a
registered political party must be decided by that party.  Some parties may 
decide that by centralised control; other may do it by
very democratic (PR) elections (primaries) of all party members.  All parties 
are coalitions, some broad, some narrow.  It is in a
party's interest to ensure that its list of candidates will appeal to the 
widest range of its potential supporters among the
electorate.  Thus all significant factions within a party are likely to be 
represented on its list.  If some faction within a party
finds it candidates consistently excluded, that faction will almost certainly 
go off and form a new party.  If some faction within a
party finds its candidates on the list, but always at the bottom (and so with 
little chance of election), that faction may well
split off and form a separate party, when its candidates will automatically be 
at the top of its list.  That does happen, especially
with closed-list party-list systems.  It is open for any group that can meet 
the requirements to be a registered political party to
present a list.  In some jurisdictions, that can include individuals standing 
as independent candidate.  But these are all
private matters (within-party), determined by the respective parties before 
the public election.

At the public election a voter can choose one party from among the various 
parties, and in open-list systems make one choice (or a
restricted choice) from among the candidates of that one party. The counting 
rules provide good proportionality among the parties
(subject to various arbitrary thresholds).  But with the commonly used 
open-list systems, the counting rules do not provide PR
within the parties.  Significant groups of voters who support a particular 
party can be seriously under-represented in terms of the
within-party balance, either through piling up massive votes for some 
particularly popular candidates or through spreading their
votes across too many candidates.  To overcome this defect, the votes must be 
transferable in some way.  And to ensure PR of the
voters, those transfers must be determined by the voters, not by some 
party-list rule in the legislation.

What you then end up with is a series of STV-PR elections within each party 
list (or with something comparable for those who don't
like STV).  The most complex open-list party-list systems go some way towards 
this.  But I have to say again, if you are going to go
to all that bother, why not  go the whole way and fully open up the voters' 
choice by removing all the restrictions of 'voting for a
party' and of 'voting within one party list'?

James





Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?

2011-07-03 Thread James Gilmour
First we have to recognise that there is no one voting system called party 
list proportional representation.  There are probably
as many variants of party-list PR as there are countries and jurisdictions 
using such a system for their public elections.
However, these party-list PR voting systems fall into two broad categories: 
closed-list party-list PR and open-list party-list
PR.

In both closed and open versions of party-list systems the order of the 
candidates in each party's list is determined by the
relevant political party.  Different countries have different rules about how 
that is to be done and different parties have
different procedures within those rules for ordering the lists.  Some parties 
exercise very strong centralised control; other
parties are much more democratic and give every member a vote.

In closed-list systems the voters can vote only for a party.  Seats are 
allocated to parties by an arithmetic formula, usually
d'Hondt (favours parties with more votes) or Sainte-Laguë (favours parties with 
fewer votes).  Candidates take the seats allocated
to their respective parties strictly in the order in which they are named on 
their parties' lists.

In open-list systems the voters can also mark a vote for a candidate but 
usually only for one candidate.  Votes for a candidate
are counted as votes for that candidate's party and seats are allocated to the 
parties by an arithmetic formula, usually d'Hondt or
Sainte-Laguë as in closed-list party-list systems.  When candidates are 
allocated to the seats won by each party, the votes for each
candidate within the relevant party are taken into account (in different ways 
in the various implementations).  Sometimes the
candidates' votes can change the order in which they are allocated to the 
party's seats.

The main objection to party-list voting systems is that they are centred on the 
registered political parties and not on the voters.
(Of course, such systems cannot be used in non-partisan elections.)  The prime 
objective of all party-list voting systems is to
deliver PR of the registered political parties.  Party-list voting systems 
entrench the political power of the political parties
(especially the central party machine) at the expense of the voters.  This is 
most certainly true of closed-list party-list voting
systems where the voters have no say in which candidates are elected.  
Open-list systems do allow the voters some say in which of
the parties' candidates should be elected, but most such systems do not provide 
proportional representation WITHIN the respective
parties.  In some situations, getting the balance of representation right 
between competing wings WITHIN one party may be as
important as getting the balance of representation right among the parties.

Whether these approaches are acceptable or not is determined by political 
philosophy.  If all you want is PR of the registered
political parties, party-list voting systems will deliver that.  The 
closed-list variety will deliver nothing more.  The
open-list variety will allow the voters (to varying degrees) some power to 
affect the balance of representation within parties,
but only the most complex of the open-list systems will deliver anything 
approaching proportionality of the voters' wishes.

But there are other views  -  that representation should be about the voters 
and not just about the registered political parties.
That the proportional representation the voting system should delver should 
be PR of the voters' wishes (as expressed by their
preferences among the candidates who offer themselves for election) and not 
just PR of the registered political parties.  There are
historical reasons why different countries have favoured one approach over the 
other, reflecting, and reflected in, differences in
political culture.

James Gilmour
Scotland (where we use 5 different voting systems for public elections, 
including 3 different PR systems, one of which is
closed-list party-list)



 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Sunday, July 03, 2011 4:50 PM
 To: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Subject: [EM] What's wrong with the party list system?
 
 
 Someone from Europe on this list recently said that they did 
 not like the party list system.  Why not?  Party list seems 
 like a fair, simple system of electing legislators who 
 represent people in approximately the same proportion that 
 they exist in the electorate.  I have not found a 
 better-sounding proportional system yet. So, what's wrong 
 with the party list system?
 
 -- 
 
 Kathy Dopp



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] C//A

2011-06-14 Thread James Gilmour
You have missed the point completely, ignoring issues of illiteracy (25% of 
adults) and disability and discrimination.

It is simpler to rank candidates 1, 2, 3, 4, etc or to rate them on a 
1 to 7 scale with the options in seven clear
columns than to engage in any combinatorial addition.

JG


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of fsimm...@pcc.edu
 Sent: Monday, June 13, 2011 11:35 PM
 To: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Subject: [EM] C//A
 
 Some folks have opined that the ballot line
 [candidate name]  (4)  (2)  (1)
 Is too complicated.
 
 How about just
 [name]  (2)  (1)
 with the understanding that the score that you assign to the 
 name is the sum of the digits of the bubbles 
 that you darken, namely zero (for the empty sum), one, two, 
 or two plus one.
 
 The only arithmetic you need to know is that  2+1 is greater 
 than 2, which is greater than one, which is 
 greater than nothing.
 
 If that is too complicated, then we are left with the only 
 thing simpler, namely Plurality ballots, which 
 means that the possible methods are Plurality, Asset, 
 Approval, and SODA.
 
 In any case, I think that the 2+1 style ballots are adequate 
 for Condorcet methods, because even when 
 your favorite is not in the top three cycle, you can still 
 rate these four candidates distinctly.
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] C//A

2011-06-12 Thread James Gilmour
fsimm...@pcc.edu   Sent: Sunday, June 12, 2011 10:42 PM
 I think the following complete description is simpler than 
 anything possible for ranked pairs:
 
 1.  Next to each candidate name are the bubbles (4) (2) (1).  
 The voter rates a candidate on a scale from 
 zero to seven by darkening the bubbles of the digits that add 
 up to the desired rating.

Given the reported levels of illiteracy and its arithmetic equivalent in the 
USA, in the UK and elsewhere, I would be extremely
doubtful if any ballot system involving such addition would be acceptable for 
public elections.  If you want voters to rate each
candidate on a scale from 1 to 7, you would need to have seven separate columns 
(bubbles).

The challenges for voting system and ballot design arising from illiteracy are 
considerable.  The separate challenges arising from
disabilities of various kinds should also not be ignored in designing for 
public elections.

James Gilmour


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Theoretical Issues In Districting

2011-06-11 Thread James Gilmour
There is an ISO standard for Geographic information -- Geodetic codes and 
parameters (ISO/TS 19127:2005) but there do not appear
to be any ISO standards for census or population.

The interest expressed here may be exclusively for USA, but other countries 
take very different approaches from that in the US.  For
example, by using the resister of electors rather than the population census.  
Some have very prescriptive limits and automatic
triggers for redistricting while others are very relaxed in almost every aspect.

A redistricting exercise is currently in progress in the UK, following the 
decision to reduce the number of MPs in the House of
Commons (UK Parliament lower house) from 650 to 600.  The Boundary Commission 
for Scotland has brought a lot of relevant information
and data together on its website at:
  http://www.bcomm-scotland.gov.uk/6th_westminster/

(There are separate Parliamentary Boundary Commissions for England, Scotland, 
Wales and Northern Ireland.  There are also separate
Boundary Commissions for Local Government within each part of the UK.)

On a related topic, the Local Government Boundary Commission for Scotland has 
conducted a consultation on how to determine the
appropriate numbers of councillors for the councils that serve the 32 very 
different local government areas within Scotland:
  http://www.lgbc-scotland.gov.uk/reviews/councillor_numbers_2011/

James Gilmour


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Warren Smith
 Sent: Saturday, June 11, 2011 3:39 PM
 To: Kristofer Munsterhjelm
 Cc: electionscience; Michael McDonald; election-methods
 Subject: Re: [EM] Theoretical Issues In Districting
 
 
  ISO standard...
 
 --that's an interesting idea.  Is there an ISO standard for
 geographic and census data? If there were, that'd be a good 
 step toward solving districting problem in practice.
 
 --
 Warren D. Smith
 http://RangeVoting.org  -- add your endorsement (by clicking 
 endorse as 1st step) and math.temple.edu/~wds/homepage/works.html
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Usability studies of ranking/rating/approval methods

2011-06-02 Thread James Gilmour
Steve
You MAY be interested to take a look at this Guidance on ballot paper design 
issued by the UK Electoral Commission, and some
associated documents:

Making your mark: design guidance for government policy-makers 
 
http://bureau-query.funnelback.co.uk/search/click.cgi?rank=7collection=electoral-commissioncomponent=0docnum=4147url=http%3A%2F%
2Fwww.dopolitics.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fpdf_file%2F0003%2F80931%2FMaking-Your-Mark-Design-Guidance-For-Government-Policy-Makers-
Web-Final-2.pdfindex_url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.dopolitics.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fpdf_file%2F0003%2F80931%2FMaking-Your-Mark-Design-G
uidance-For-Government-Policy-Makers-Web-Final-2.pdfsearch_referer=

Making your mark: designing for democracy   
 
http://bureau-query.funnelback.co.uk/search/click.cgi?rank=3collection=electoral-commissioncomponent=0docnum=11545url=http%3A%2F
%2Fwww.electoralcommission.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fword_doc%2F0008%2F67184%2FMaking-your-mark-Project-summary-Sept-2008.docindex
_url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.electoralcommission.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fword_doc%2F0008%2F67184%2FMaking-your-mark-Project-summary-Sept
-2008.docsearch_referer=

Uservision report on ballot paper design 
 
http://bureau-query.funnelback.co.uk/search/click.cgi?rank=1collection=electoral-commissioncomponent=0docnum=12313url=http%3A%2F
%2Fwww.electoralcommission.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fpdf_file%2F0008%2F77687%2FUservision-report-on-ballot-paper-design---FINAL.pdf
index_url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.electoralcommission.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fpdf_file%2F0008%2F77687%2FUservision-report-on-ballot-pap
er-design---FINAL.pdfsearch_referer=

The Electoral Commission Ballot Paper Testing Summary Final Report 
 
http://bureau-query.funnelback.co.uk/search/click.cgi?rank=2collection=electoral-commissioncomponent=0docnum=12311url=http%3A%2F
%2Fwww.electoralcommission.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fpdf_file%2F0007%2F77686%2FThe-Electoral-Commission-Ballot-Paper-Testing-Summar
y-Final-Report.pdfindex_url=http%3A%2F%2Fwww.electoralcommission.org.uk%2F__data%2Fassets%2Fpdf_file%2F0007%2F77686%2FThe-Electoral
-Commission-Ballot-Paper-Testing-Summary-Final-Report.pdfsearch_referer=

James Gilmour



 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Steve Wolfman
 Sent: Wednesday, June 01, 2011 8:53 PM
 To: election-meth...@electorama.com
 Subject: [EM] Usability studies of ranking/rating/approval methods
 
 
 There's been some recent discussion of which ballots are 
 easiest to use.  
 Does anyone know of published (experimental) studies of usability of 
 non-plurality ballots (perhaps vs. plurality ballots)?
 
 I'd be happy to take personal responses and summarize for 
 anyone who would 
 rather not post to the list.
 
   Thanks,
 
   Steve
 
 P.S. From what I've looked at so far: A good starting point into the 
 literature on usability for plurality ballots is Sarah 
 Everett's thesis: 
 The Usability of Electronic Voting Machines and How Votes Can 
 Be Changed 
 Without Detection.  That references Herrnson et al's book Voting 
 Technology: The Not-So-Simple Act.., also a substantial work 
 in the area. 
 Both discuss usability of a few non-standard ballot features 
 (e.g., review 
 screens/VVPAT), and at least the latter discusses select 2 
 contests. 
 However, neither addresses ranked/rated/approval ballots.  In 
 the US, NIST 
 has developed usability standards for voting (specifically 
 for non-ranked 
 contests).  Here's NIST's voting homepage 
 http://www.nist.gov/itl/vote/, 
 but I haven't found the navigation path to the specific usability 
 benchmark document yet; so, see: 
 http://vote.nist.gov/meeting-08172007/Usability-Benchmarks-081707.pdf
 
 -
 Steven Wolfman, Ph.D.
 Sr Instructor, UBC CS
 
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info
 


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Statement by this list (was Remember toby Nixon)

2011-05-28 Thread James Gilmour
  On 27.5.2011, at 10.01, Jameson Quinn wrote:
  1. We draw up a statement which details the serious problems 
  with plurality in the US context, and states that there are 
  solutions.

 Juho Laatu  Sent: Friday, May 27, 2011 9:43 PM 
 Good approach. I have one comment on the target statement. 
 Expression problems with plurality in the US context 
 contains the assumption that the traditional two-party system 
 in not the correct solution for the US. 

I would respectfully suggest that this statement is not correct.  I don't think 
JQ's statement says or implies anything about the
traditional two-party system.  But even if the electors and voters in the USA 
wanted and voted only for the traditional two-party
system, there could be, and probably would be, problems with plurality, even 
in the US context.  Plurality frequently distorts the
voters' wishes, is inherently unstable, and even when it delivers acceptably 
balanced representation overall there are often
electoral deserts where one party or the other has almost no representation 
despite having significant voting support there, even
when there are only two parties.

And I think you need to distinguish between the two types of election that 
occur in the US context: election to a single-office
(city mayor, state governor, etc); and election to a representative assembly 
(city council, state legislature with upper and lower
houses, federal legislature with upper and lower houses).  These two types of 
election present different opportunities for securing
representation of the voters within a system of representative democracy.  
These are more fundamental issues that I would suggest
you need to address, and they are quite independent of any consideration of the 
number of parties (or the number of effective
parties) that might come later.

JG













Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why is wikipedia so biased pro-IRV?

2011-02-28 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer Munsterhjelm  Sent: Monday, February 28, 2011 1:18 PM
 
 James Gilmour wrote:
  Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Friday, February 25, 2011 2:29 PM
  I'm not a UK politics expert, but it seems this is a minimal concession,
  of the sort one would see in negotiation. AV/IRV doesn't really lead to 
  multiparty systems, if Australia is to be any judge. Instead, you get 
  two large parties and one middle sized party (as in Australia's Labor 
  and LibNats), which is an improvement from Plurality, and definitely so 
  from the point of view of the Liberal Democrats (who could become the 
  middle sized party).
  
  The UK already has a multi-party system - all under FPTP.-  at least as  
  measured by votes. Of course, not as measured by seats - but that's 
  FPTP.
 
 Although I was thinking of measured by seats, that's interesting. What 
 keeps the Liberal Democrat voters from going lesser-of-two-evils?

I can't answer that directly, except perhaps to suggest their supporters are 
more concerned to keep the political equivalent of the
one true faith.  Support for the two largest parties is at the lowest it has 
been in modern times - see:
  
http://www.jamesgilmour.f2s.com/Percentage-Votes-for-Two-Largest-Parties-UK-GEs-1945-2010.pdf

So far as Westminster elections are concerned, England has three significant 
parties, and as Bob has already pointed out, Scotland
and Wales both have four.

In the general election of 1997 there was a lot of local tactical voting (i.e. 
voting for a candidate of a party did not sincerely
want to see elected) with the aim of getting the Conservatives out (or to 
prevent them from winning where they had been a close
second in the previous election).  That tactical voting was particularly 
successful in Scotland and Wales because the Tories did not
win a single seat in either country despite having 17% and 20% of the votes 
respectively.  That result was a great political victory
(to give the Conservatives a bloody nose), but it was a travesty in terms of 
democratic representation of the voters.


 
  US members might be interested to know that more than two-thirds of 
  the 649 MPs elected in the 2010 UK general election are minority 
  members - elected with less than half of the votes in their individual  
  constituencies (electoral districts). See:
 http://www.jamesgilmour.f2s.com/UK-MPs-GE-2010-Minority-Members-12Jan11.pdf

  
  AV+ or STV/MMP would have been better, but alas.
  
  STV-PR would certainly have been better than AV (= IRV) from every 
  perspective. But AV+ would have been a disaster. Remember, AV+ was 
  designed deliberately to distort the seats-to-votes so that one or  
  other of the two largest parties would nearly always have an overall 
  majority of seats for only a minority of the votes.
 
 I thought AV+ was just MMP with AV rather than FPTP as the base. MMP 
 itself, as far as I know, keeps a number of direct election seats, then 
 counts the wasted preferences and compensates by using list seats so 
 that one's vote can count even if it doesn't elect the direct seat. If 
 so, it shouldn't be biased in favor of the two largest parties unless 
 the calculation itself is.

No, AV+ is not simply MMP with AV in the single-member electoral districts 
instead of FPTP.  The clue is in the name  -  it is AV
with a (very) little bit added on rather than any real kind of proportional 
system.  It would give more proportional results than
FPTP, but it would still distort the overall votes so that one or other of the 
two main parties would have an overall majority of
the seats for a minority of the votes in most elections.

In Jenkins' AV+ there was no national tally of the votes.  Instead the top-up 
correction was to be applied separately within each
of the proposed 80 electoral regions.  Each electoral region would have between 
3 and 10 single-member electoral districts  - mostly
5 to 9.  BUT there would be only ONE or TWO top-up seats in each electoral 
region.  So the proportionality correction would have
been only 1 in 8 in some cases, but mostly 2 in the regions with 7, 8 or 9 
districts.  So the results would still have been horribly
distorted in relation to the votes  -  but that was what was wanted!!!

You must also remember that the MMP used to elect the Scottish Parliament and 
the Welsh Assembly is a regionalised version.  There
is no national tally of the list (party) votes.  Instead the list votes are 
tallied within electoral regions.  In Scotland there are
8 electoral regions, containing 8, 9 or 10 single-member electoral districts.  
Each electoral region returns 7 regional members.  So
the MMP proportionality here is worked out for regions returning 15, 16 or 17 
MSPs.  That's quite different from MMP in New Zealand
or federal elections in Germany.  Also, we have no overhang correction of any 
kind in Scotland, but we do have lots of
overhang!!

 
  Full MMP  would have been better in terms of party proportionality

Re: [EM] Why is wikipedia so biased pro-IRV?

2011-02-26 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Friday, February 25, 2011 2:29 PM
 
 I'm not a UK politics expert, but it seems this is a minimal 
 concession,
 of the sort one would see in negotiation. AV/IRV doesn't really lead to 
 multiparty systems, if Australia is to be any judge. Instead, you get 
 two large parties and one middle sized party (as in Australia's Labor 
 and LibNats), which is an improvement from Plurality, and definitely so 
 from the point of view of the Liberal Democrats (who could become the 
 middle sized party).

The UK already has a multi-party system  -  all under FPTP.- at least as 
measured by votes.  Of course, not as measured by seats  -
but that's FPTP.

US members might be interested to know that more than two-thirds of the 649 MPs 
elected in the 2010 UK general election are minority
members  -  elected with less than half of the votes in their individual 
constituencies (electoral districts).  See:
  http://www.jamesgilmour.f2s.com/UK-MPs-GE-2010-Minority-Members-12Jan11.pdf



 AV+ or STV/MMP would have been better, but alas.

STV-PR would certainly have been better than AV (= IRV) from every perspective. 
 But AV+ would have been a disaster.  Remember, AV+
was designed deliberately to distort the seats-to-votes so that one or other of 
the two largest parties would nearly always have an
overall majority of seats for only a minority of the votes.  Full MMP would 
have been better in terms of party proportionality, but
that is all.  MMP, with two very different kinds of elected member, brings a 
raft of new problems which would be high price to pay
for party PR.  We have MMP in the Scottish Parliament (we call it AMS), but we 
want to change to STV-PR.

James Gilmour



-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com
Version: 10.0.1204 / Virus Database: 1435/3469 - Release Date: 02/26/11


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] electing a variable number of seats

2011-02-17 Thread James Gilmour
Charlie
I see two problems here.

1.  You do not give the conditions under which the constitution of this 
organisation allows the number of board members to be
varied.

2.  More importantly, someone needs to define the purpose of this election a 
great deal better.  Who would have the power to add one
extra winner with a view to improving representation and who would decide 
what improved representation might be?  And just who
exactly would have the power to reduce the number elected board members with a 
view to eliminating polarizing candidates and who
would decide that the last winner was a polarizing candidate who should be 
excluded?

The purpose of board elections in democratic organisations is usually to fill 
the current vacancies with the requisite number of
candidates who best represent the members who vote in the election.  It seems a 
bit strange, to say the VERY least, that someone
(undefined) should have the power to vary that by adding a board member to 
improve representation or by excluding an otherwise
elected board member who is considered polarizing.  If the members of the 
organisation, using a fair and properly representative
voting system, elect a polarizing candidate, it is surely not for  anyone to 
have the power to over-ride that democratic decision.

Or have I missed something?

James Gilmour


 -Original Message-
 From: election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com 
 [mailto:election-methods-boun...@lists.electorama.com] On 
 Behalf Of Charlie DeTar
 Sent: Thursday, February 17, 2011 3:39 AM
 To: election-methods@lists.electorama.com
 Subject: [EM] electing a variable number of seats
 
 
 Howdy,
 
 I'm on the board of a small non-profit, and have been tasked 
 with revising the portion of the bylaws that defines how to 
 elect the board of directors.  Having had some exposure to 
 better election methods through a colleague, I'm interested 
 in exploring how we might use a ranked voting system 
 effectively.  Most of the methods I've seen, however, are 
 intended for electing a single winner -- and for the board of 
 directors, we have multiple seats.  Additionally, the number 
 of seats is variable.
 
 I'm looking for methods that would more or less optimally 
 (by variable definitions of optimal) elect a variable number 
 of people.  Single Transferable Vote seems to be the most 
 talked-about multi-winner ranked system; but the vote 
 transfer process requires a pre-defined number of seats to 
 fill.  It seems like the option to have a variable number of 
 seats opens up possibilities for improving representation by 
 adding a winner, or eliminating polarizing candidates by removing one.
 
 Thoughts?
 
 best,
 Charlie
 
 Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em 
 for list info
 

-
No virus found in this message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com
Version: 10.0.1204 / Virus Database: 1435/3448 - Release Date: 02/16/11


Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Thoughts on a nomination simulation

2010-06-18 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Thursday, June 17, 2010 9:58 AM
 In a parliamentary system, I imagine it would be possible for the party 
 leadership to decide (in the manner that they decide a list under party 
 list PR). How do parties in actual single-winner district parliamentary 
 countries (like England or Canada) select their candidates?

For a UK perspective, see:  
  Candidate Selection   
The report of the Commission on Candidate Selection, by Peter Riddell. June 
2005. ISBN 0 903291 24 X
   PDF at:  http://www.electoral-reform.org.uk/downloads/Candidate%20Report.pdf

Since that report was written the Conservative Party has experimented with one 
(or two ?) open primary elections to select its
candidate for the constituency  -  all postal voting open to all electors 
registered to vote in the relevant constituency.  This was
an expensive and pointless exercise as it failed completely to address any of 
the real problems afflicting the voting system used to
elect MPs to the House of Commons at Westminster.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.829 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2945 - Release Date: 06/17/10 
19:35:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] the intrinsic value of the metric of *strength* of personalpreference (was: Re: Compatibility)

2010-05-05 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Wednesday, May 05, 2010 6:29 PM
 BTW, Juho, I heard a BBC news story about your election tomorrow  
 regarding the desirability of FPTP vs. proportional methods in  
 electing Parliament.  so it sounds like that the UK, with its new Lib- 
 Dem party, is also being confronted by the same problems.  I don't  
 quite get it, though.  aren't MPs elected out of geographic  
 districts?  are there more than one MP elected in any given district?   
 if it's only one MP per district, how can a proportional method be  
 used?  how can the losing votes in one district be transferred to  
 another district to help elect someone there?  you would *have* to  
 have more than one candidate elected per district with all candidates  
 running at large, no?  if it's one MP per district, it's a single- 
 winner election (and then, of course, I would advocate for 
 Condorcet,  in a 3+ party context).

This wasn't addressed to me, but as a UK voter and UK campaigner for voting 
reform for more than 45 years, I may be qualified to
comment.

The problem with the FPTP voting system in the UK it not new  -  it has been 
apparent since at least 1900.  And there have been
several attempts to reform it, with some very near misses along the way.  MANY 
of us hope this 2010 general election will the last
FPTP election for the UK Parliament at Westminster.  (We use six different 
voting systems for public elections in the UK.  Of these,
three are PR voting systems.)

The Liberal Democrat Party is not new.  This party (or its immediate 
predecessors) has received significant support for many years.
The UK has a multi-party Parliament, although the defective FPTP voting system 
has ensured that the voters wishes were so distorted
that only two parties have been able to form governments, and nearly always 
with a substantial majority over all parties though no
party has won even half of the votes in any general election since 1945.

At present all 650 MPs are elected from single-member districts (here called 
constituencies).  It is impossible to have a PR voting
system that is based only on any voting system exclusively within singe-member 
districts.

The main thrust for reform is for STV-PR with sensibly sized multi-member 
electoral districts.  For example, Edinburgh presently
elects 5 MPs from 5 single-member constituencies.  The City of Edinburgh should 
be ONE 5-member STV-PR electoral district.
Similarly, the City of Glasgow should be a 7-member electoral district.  In 
rural areas the district magnitude could be less, with
even one or two single-member districts reflecting remoteness and long-standing 
political realities.

The outgoing government (Labour Party) offered a referendum on the Alternative 
Vote (= IRV) if it were re-elected, but this is a
cynical political ploy as the Alternative Vote would be electoral reform that 
would not deliver PR and would tend to favour the
Labour Party  -  at least, it would have done on the basis of polling returns 
before the election campaign started.  There have been
some significant changes in voting intention during the election campaign and 
AV (= IRV) could perhaps work very badly against the
Labour Party.  Serious reformers are opposed to the AV nonsense!

The numbers of candidates standing in the present FPTP single-member districts 
varies widely; I think 14 may be the maximum this
time.  In the five Edinburgh single-member constituencies (where I live) the 
numbers of candidates are: 4, 5, 6, 7 and 9.  But if
Edinburgh were one 5-member electoral district for STV-PR, the total number of 
candidates would likely be less that the present
total of 31 because none of the four main parties would nominate 5 candidates.

We already use STV-PR for public elections within the UK and it works very 
well.  STV-PR should adopted for the UK Parliament as
well.

James Gilmour



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.814 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2854 - Release Date: 05/04/10 
19:27:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Proportional election method needed for the Czech Greenparty - Council elections

2010-05-03 Thread James Gilmour
Peter Zbornik   Sent: Monday, May 03, 2010 12:07 PM
  On Mon, May 3, 2010 at 1:00 PM, Markus Schulze 
  If I understand Peter Zbornik correctly, then he
  wants a ranking of the members of the council, so
  that it is clear who the 2nd vice president, the
 3rd vice president, the 4th vice president, etc., is.

 Markus Schulze understands me correctly.

If your party wants to elect a council that fairly (proportionately) represents 
the wishes of those party members who vote in its
election, I would recommend that you use STV-PR for this purpose.  Which 
version of STV-PR counting rules you use will make little
difference to the outcome compared to the differences between using any version 
of STV-PR and using other voting systems.

If your party then wants to identify from WITHIN that representative Council, a 
President (chair-person) and two or more
Vice-Presidents, you should NOT use the order of election in the first STV-PR 
election for that purpose.  Instead, you should
conduct a series of STV-PR counts, using the same ballots, for diminishing 
numbers of places to produce a reverse-ordered list from
among those already elected to the Council.  The top positions can then be 
filled by those Council members who emerge as winners
in the successive elections, for one place, for two places, etc.  This 
procedure is described here:
  http://www.cix.co.uk/~rosenstiel/stv/orderstv.htm
This approach will maintain the overall balance of the Council as determined by 
the members who vote and identify those elected
members who should take the top posts.

STV-PR has been used in this way by several different political parties in the 
UK when they are required to produce ordered lists of
candidates for closed-list party-list PR elections.  NB.  I do NOT recommend 
anyone to adopt closed-list party-list PR voting
systems for any elections (public or private), but such ordered-list voting 
systems have been imposed on us by UK governments and so
the parties must produce the ordered lists if they wish to participate in these 
elections.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.814 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2851 - Release Date: 05/03/10 
07:27:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


[EM] FW: Tasmanian Greens get 21% of first choice votes, 5 seats of 25

2010-03-25 Thread James Gilmour
Elections in two Australian states have just been held.

In Tasmania, the lower House of Assembly elected by PR-STV has 25 seats in 5 x 
5-seat constituencies, so gives good proportional
representation.
See
http://www.abc.net.au/elections/tas/2010/
and
http://www.electoral.tas.gov.au

In South Australia the lower house is elected by instant runoff aka the 
alternative vote, STV in single seat constituencies, so
with 7.8% of first choice votes the Greens have no seats. It's no more 
proportional than our first-past-the-post.
http://www.abc.net.au/elections/sa/2010

However, the situation in the SA upper house, the Legislative Council, is 
different. Half its 22 members are elected at a time, and
the whole state is one PR-STV constituency. so with 6.5% of first choices the 
Greens have one seat.
http://www.abc.net.au/elections/sa/2010/guide/lc-results.htm

If you look at the details you see that the Australian Greens are able to run 
strong women candidates, and with PR-STV proportional
representation, to elect them.

Doug Woodard, St. Catharines, Ontario

Fw by JG

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.791 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2769 - Release Date: 03/25/10 
07:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Condorcet How?

2010-03-24 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson  wrote:
 It seems that what Fairvote want is PR-STV.
 
 The hope is presumably, that if they can get voters used to 
 ranked ballots and eliminations with IRV, they can then argue 
 that moving onto PR-STV is just changing to the multiseat 
 version of IRV.

Surely a major factor in determining the strategy for any campaign to reform 
voting systems in the USA must be the large number of
single-office single-winner elections you have?  This must make any US campaign 
more complex than the similar campaigns in the UK.
In turn, the campaign strategy will be more complex.

Until England decided to have a few (VERY few!!) directly elected city mayors, 
we had NO single-office single-winner public
elections.  This is why, since 1894, our focus has always been on PR.  That 
simple focus on one objective makes campaigning simpler
and make devising campaign strategy simpler.  The prime PR target has yet to be 
achieved (UK Parliament at Westminster), but every
other voting system reform in the UK during the past 15 years has been to 
introduce a PR voting system of one kind or another for
various representative assemblies at different levels of government.

James
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.791 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2767 - Release Date: 03/24/10 
07:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Proportional Representation Systems I'd Support

2010-03-24 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank   Sent: Tuesday, March 23, 2010 11:01 PM

In relation to the Swiss Federal Parliament election system

 It is like a cumulative voting version of MMP, but there is 
 no mechanism for a candidate to win without being a member of a party.

No, it's not at all like MMP.  In MMP half or more of the members are elected 
from single-member electoral districts (usually by
FPTP).  The additional members in MMP are elected by party-list (usually 
closed-list) taking into account the single-member seats
already won by each party.  That is quite different from the party-list voting 
system used for the Swiss Conseil National.

JG

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.791 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2767 - Release Date: 03/24/10 
07:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Proportional Representation Systems I'd Support

2010-03-24 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank  Sent: Wednesday, March 24, 2010 5:31 PM
 Sorry, I wasn't clear at all. 

No, it certainly wasn't clear.

 I was thinking of the decoy 
 list issue with MMP.

I don't think this is at all a helpful way of looking at the Swiss CN voting 
system.


 What I meant was that it is like MMP in that the voters have 
 a party vote and an additional vote using a different method.

No, it is not at all like MMP in that.  ALL the votes are party votes.  All the 
votes are used to allocate seats to parties and then
the votes within parties are used to decide which candidates should fill the 
allocated seats.  Importantly, all the members are
elected on an equal basis  -  quite unlike MMP.


 It is immune to decoy lists since it doesn't elect anyone 
 directly.

OK.


 The additional vote is purely used to decide which 
 members of the party are elected.

No, because for every cumulated vote you must strike out a corresponding 
vote.  Of course, when it comes to the allocation of
candidates to seats, the cumulated votes do have a separate effect.


  Also, it is single 
 constituency based.

This I do not follow.  The country is divided into constituencies = 
electoral districts.  The numbers of members elected from
each electoral district ranges from one (very few) to 35.  So there is a 
regionalised element in this system.  Perhaps you meant
that the country was treated as one constituency (electoral district) for the 
initial allocation of seats to parties?


 It does have the advantage that it is summable.

Coming from a UK background, where all ballots are always taken to a counting 
centre irrespective of the voting system, this is
irrelevant for far as I am concerned.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.791 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2767 - Release Date: 03/24/10 
07:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Proportional Representation Systems I'd Support

2010-03-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Monday, March 22, 2010 9:24 PM
 I think your more complex party list PR (with cross endorsement) could 
 work while still passing all three criteria. It's certainly summable and 
 proportional, so the only difficulty would be in making it monotone. 
 Simply distributing excess turns it STV-like. Perhaps something similar 
 to my divisor trick could be used, but I'm not sure how.

This principle is well-known in electoral science where it described by the 
French term apparentenement.  It has been used in
party-list PR voting systems at different times in France, Italy and 
Switzerland.  In France and Italy the apparentenement was
determined by the parties.  In the (much) more complicated Swiss system, the 
apparentenement is determined by each individual
voter.

The allocation of seats to parties is determined by applying either the d'Hondt 
formula or the Sainte-Laguë formula to the votes,
summed over the apparentenement partner-parties as necessary.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.791 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2762 - Release Date: 03/21/10 
19:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Voting systems theory and proportional representation vssimple representation.

2010-03-13 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Saturday, March 13, 2010 8:54 PM
 Abd ul, I agree with virtually all you say that I had time to 
 read, but would prefer party list voting over asset voting 
 simply because it forces the #1 elector, as you put it, to 
 state in advance who he will nominate with any excess votes 
 and also in some systems gives the voters a chance to vote 
 for changes in the order of the list.  This gives options to 
 those voters who are well-informed that asset voting does not.

But these party list voting systems fail to deliver proportionality WITHIN the 
respective parties.  In some political situations,
achieving the voters' desired proportionality WITHIN a party can be almost as 
important as achieving proportionality between or
among the parties.

It should also be noted that all party list voting systems reinforce the 
dominance of the political parties in the whole political
system.  In some political cultures voters already think the political parties 
are too dominant.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.733 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2743 - Release Date: 03/13/10 
07:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Smith, FPP fails Minimal Defense and Clone-Winner

2010-03-10 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank   Sent: Thursday, March 11, 2010 12:13 AM
 I had a look at the 2008 House election results, and there 
 are a reasonable number of districts where one candidate got 
 more than 2/3, so maybe it isn't as big an issue as I 
 thought.  OTOH, maybe it was that in those districts, the 
 minority knew that they had no chance, so didn't bother 
 turning out.  Maybe the minority in that district would be 
 able to manage 1/3 of the votes.

You should bear in mind that the results of such FPTP elections in the USA are 
anomalous in relation to FPTP elections elsewhere
because the US elections are affected by successful incumbent gerrymandering 
and by the effect of primary elections.  I suspect that
if these two distorting effects were removed, you would see a very different 
picture, much like that from FPTP elections in Canada
or in the UK.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.733 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2734 - Release Date: 03/10/10 
07:33:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV ballot pile count (proof of closed form)

2010-02-05 Thread James Gilmour
Abd ul-Rahman Lomax   Sent: Friday, February 05, 2010 4:50 PM
CUT
 Practically speaking, I'd assume, the precincts would be provided 
 with a spreadsheet showing the possible combinations, and they would 
 report the combinations using the spreadsheet, transmitting it. So 
 some cells would be blank or zero. With 5 candidates on the ballot, 
 the spreadsheet has gotten large, but it's still doable. What happens 
 if preferential voting encourages more candidates to file, as it 
 tends to do? 23 candidates in San Francisco? Even with three-rank 
 RCV, it gets hairy.

Respectfully, I would suggest this would NOT be a wise way to collect the data. 
 As I pointed out in my e-mail that correctly listed
the maximum possible number of preference profiles for various numbers of 
candidates, the actual number of preference profiles in
any election (or any one precinct) with a significant number of candidates, 
will be limited by the number of voters.  Further,
because some (many) voters will choose the same profiles of preferences, the 
actual number of preference profiles will likely be
even lower  -  as in the Dáil Éireann election I quoted.

Thus a spreadsheet containing all possible preference profiles would be 
unnecessarily large and the probability of making mistakes
in data entry would likely be greater than if each precinct recorded only the 
numbers for each profile actually found in that
precinct.

CUT

 There is a way to avoid such massive reporting, which is to report 
 interactively, which is what is done in Australia. Only one set of 
 totals is reported from a precinct at a time, the totals for the 
 current round. (which can be just uncovered votes due to eliminations 
 that have been reported to the precinct from central tabulation.)
 
 However, the problem with this is that a single error in a precinct 
 can require, then, all precincts to have to retabulate. 

Yes, this distributed counting would work.  But there is an even simpler 
solution  -  take all the ballots to one counting centre
and then sort and count only the ballots that are necessary to determine the 
winner (or winners in an STV-PR election).  That what
has been done for public elections in Ireland and the UK for many decades and 
it works well without problems.  But I do appreciate
that is far too simple and practical a solution and it suffers from NMH.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.733 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2669 - Release Date: 02/05/10 
07:35:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Professorial Office Picking

2010-01-25 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank   Sent: Monday, January 25, 2010 2:17 PM
 Something like a CTT auction could be used here.
 
 Each bidder submits a sealed ballot containing the dollar 
 value of each office.
 
 For all possible permutations work out the sum of all the bids.
 
 Assign the offices to the arrangement that gives the highest sum.

Interesting.  Maybe some parallels here with linear programming approaches to 
timetabling  -  maximising resource utilisation for
rooms of different sizes, student classes of different sizes and lecturers with 
different commitments across the groups of students.
(I do not have any details and I have never been involved in timetabling so I 
don't know how well these approaches work in
practice.)

James Gilmour
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2644 - Release Date: 01/25/10 
07:36:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:25 AM
 On Jan 21, 2010, at 7:05 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
 
  N Unique Preference Profiles
  2 4
  3 15
  ...
 
  then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you 
 ostensibly need 
  4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.
 
 
  If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique  
  preference profiles are:
  A   
  B   
  AB 
  BA
 
 
 
 what, on a ballot, is the consequential difference in meaning between  
 A and AB?  what effect does a ballot marked AB have over one  
 marked just A (or vise versa) in *any* election method that uses  
 ranked ballots?

In terms of preference profiles the question is completely irrelevant.  A 
and AB are two different preference profiles.  So
the possible numbers of preference profiles for given numbers of candidates 
are, I think, correctly stated in the table in my
earlier post.

How the STV counting rules handle the two preference profiles A and AB is 
a different matter.  Some STV counting rules handle
these two profiles identically.  But for some other STV counting rules the 
profiles A and AB are handled differently.  This
second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes to the 
bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated differently 
from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable (exhausted)', but the 
AB ballot would be transferred to A.

This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean it has not 
been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,
sadly, Scotland.  It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my 
vote could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible place, e.g. 
12th out of 12 candidates.  Following on from the
concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency voting, as 
in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances will her 
vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter end rule 
undermines this.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy
I think my post made clear that I was referring only to preference profiles.  
I was not dealing with the situation where some
artificial, and highly undesirable, restriction had been placed on the numbers 
of rankings the voters could mark.

I think my comments about the counting procedure adopted in Minneapolis should 
have indicated that I am well aware of the
restrictions that can be imposed.  But note that in Minneapolis the restriction 
was an artificial one imposed by the certified
counting machines available for use in the precincts.  There is nothing in the 
Minneapolis Election Ordinance that imposes such a
restriction.  So when Minneapolis can obtain certified counting machines that 
can deal with fully ranked ballots, there will be no
such restriction in practice.

James

 Behalf Of Kathy Dopp
 Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 12:43 AM
 Subject: Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)
 
 
 James,
 
 Your formulas below are only correct in the case that voters 
 are allowed to rank all the candidates who run for an 
 election contest. That may be true in Australia, but is not 
 true in the US where typically voters are allowed to rank up 
 to only three candidates.
 
 I put the general formula that applies to *all* cases with n 
 candidates and with r rankings allowed in my paper on IRV 
 that I wrote a year or two ago:
 
 Realities Mar Instant Runoff Voting 
 http://electionmathematics.org/ucvAnalysis/US/RCV-IRV/InstantR
 unoffVotingFlaws.pdf
 
 
 Because it's hard to write a summation, fraction formula, 
 etc. here I'll let you look it up. It's on page 6 of the doc 
 linked above.
 
 Cheers,
 
 Kathy
 
 
 
  From: James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
  I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the 
  numbers of possible unique preference profiles for 
 increasing numbers 
  of candidates (N) as follows:
 
  N       Unique Preference Profiles
  2       4
  3       15
  4       64
  5       325
  6       1,956
  7       13,699
  8       109,600
  9       986,409
  10      9,864,100
  11      108,505,111
  12      1,302,061,344
  13      16,926,797,485
  14      236,975,164,804
  15      3,554,627,472,075
  16      56,874,039,553,216
  17      966,858,672,404,689
  18      17,403,456,103,284,400
  19      330,665,665,962,404,000
  20      6,613,313,319,248,080,000
 
 
  Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible 
  number of unique preference profiles will be limited by the 
 number of 
  voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 
 candidates, the 
  maximum possible number of preference profiles would be 
 10,000 and not 
  1,302,061,344.
 
  In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even 
  lower, as significant numbers of voters would record identical 
  patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency 
 for the D?il 
  ?ireann election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804 
  possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 
 25,101 unique 
  preference profiles.
 
 
  The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique 
  preference profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was 
  unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than 
  three preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of 
 candidates. I 
  understand the full preference profiles, probably at 
 precinct level, 
  will be published on the City website, but they are not there yet.
 
  James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 1:42 PM
 
 OK James. As I said before, I agree with you that you were 
 giving the total number of profiles *if* voters were allowed 
 to rank all candidates, which they were not allowed to do in 
 Minneapolis or elsewhere in the US public elections if I am right.

In STV elections (STV, IRV, RCV) there should be NO restrictions of any kind on 
the number of rankings each voter may mark, up to
the limit of the number of candidates.  The voters should be completely free to 
mark as many or as few rankings as each wishes.


 Further, I think that Robert is correct, that one could 
 collapse the last N profiles into prior profiles if that is 
 the system that is used (allowing ranking all candidates), 
 although I do not think that gives any advantage, 
 practically, to the counting process and may even complicate it.

As I explained in my earlier post, whether or not you can do that depends on 
the version of the STV counting rules you have to use.


 My formula provides the more practical number of how many 
 profiles are allowed to be cast by voters and how many 
 profiles are needed if one wants to count the number of votes 
 cast for each profile and make IRV precinct-summable for an 
 actual election.

But if you do not report the complete preference profiles, down the last 
preference position (whether or not it is relevant to the
count), you reduce the transparency of the process.  The full ballot data 
should be published as soon as possible after the
election.  To provide complete information in the smallest size, the STV ballot 
data should be published as preference profiles,
i.e. COMPLETE preference profiles.  The BLT format is convenient for this.  The 
full ballot data from the 2007 STV-PR local
government elections in the City of Glasgow (Scotland) were published on the 
City Council's website as very soon after the count
closed on the day after polling.  They are still all there for inspection.


 Obviously Condorcet counting methods are much simpler to make 
 precinct-summable than IRV, requiring far fewer number of 
 sums per precinct as the number of candidates increases.

If you are going to do a manual sort of the ballots, then making three piles 
for each pair-wise comparison (AB, BA, neither
ranked) would involve less work than sorting to complete preference profiles.  
But if you have sensible processing equipment that
task is trivial and the difference irrelevant.


 I think one thing that some election methods experts 
 sometimes fail to consider are the election administration 
 practicalities that are crucial to whether or not a method is 
 functionally practical to provide public oversight over.

The practicalities of election administration are extremely important and as a 
returning officer for some elections, I am well aware
of that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put artificial or 
convenient limitations on the democratic process.


 I am fully aware that it is voting system technology, costs, 
 and the increasing impracticality of manually auditing the 
 election if the full range of preference profiles is allowed, 
 if one is making an attempt to use paper ballots, that limits 
 the number of choices a voter may fill out.  I've studied 
 this issue for 7 years now.

We have absolutely no problems with any of this in our STV public elections in 
the UK.  We always take all our paper ballots to one
counting centre for each electoral district.  In Northern Ireland, the ballots 
are sorted and counted manually, under scrutiny.  In
Scotland in 2007 we used optical scanning equipment and OCR to produce the vote 
vector for each ballot and the vote vectors were
then consolidated into preference profiles for the STV counting program.  All 
the ballot handling was done under scrutiny.  There
are always some who are unhappy with the results (defeated candidates and their 
supporters!), but the process has not been
challenged.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 4:54 PM
 James, you are using a straw man argument with me, setting up 
 a false premise that I said something I never did, 

Kathy, I was not setting up any straw man argument with you or anyone else.  I 
simply stated what a preference profile is and the
possible numbers of such profiles.  Anything else is not a preference profile 
and is irrelevant.

Of course, no-one in their right mind (or not under legal restraint) would do a 
manual count of STV ballots by sorting to preference
profiles.  It is completely unnecessary and would extend time taken for the 
count very greatly.  Sorting STV ballots to preference
profiles makes sense only in computerised counting.


 To require, as you suggest that all election be administered 
 in a way that allows all voters to fully rank all candidates 
 may sounds nice

No, Kathy it is not something that sounds nice  -  it is an essential 
requirement for the proper implementation of democratic
choice.  Any artificiality imposed constraint on that is a restriction of that 
democratic choice.  But I am aware that factors of
administrative convenience outweigh such considerations in some jurisdictions 
 -  it must be so, else they would never be
tolerated.


 and would eliminate one of the problems with 
 IRV, but with so many election contests on one ballot here in 
 the US, it would be costly and possibly impractical unless 
 you insist on using inauditable, easily hacked, electronic 
 ballots and touchscreen devices rather than auditable voter 
 marked paper ballots.

No, Kathy, here in the UK we do NOT use any easily hacked, electronic ballots 
and touchscreen devices.  We use good old-fashioned
paper ballots which we mark with a stubby pencil secured to the polling booth 
by a short length of string!  It is very old
technology, but it works, and it is extremely flexible in that this voting 
method (paper and pencil) can be adapted to any voting
system (and we use five different voting systems for public elections in 
Scotland).  And of course, where electronic counting is
employed, we always have the original paper ballots should anyone demand an 
audit.


 As I said earlier, if paper ballots are required, the length 
 of the paper ballot must be unlimited if the number of 
 candidates who can run for office is unlimited and you want 
 voters to be able to fully rank (not that most voters would want to.)

Length has not been a problem.


 Dealing with practical election administration issues seem to 
 be very low down on the totem pole for most electoral methods 
 people it seems.

I cannot speak for any other EM member, but practical election administration 
is an important priority for me, especially as I am
the returning officer for some elections and the supervising officer for some 
others.


CUT

 Sorting ballots into 
 piles and confusing subpiles only works for IRV and does not 
 work for STV, except if there are no transferrable votes or 
 you want to cut up pieces of ballots or xerox copies of 
 ballots (what a confusing mess that would be.)

If by STV you mean STV-PR (a multi-seat election), this statement is 
nonsense.  IF you are sorting ballots into unique preference
profiles, that is as easily done for STV-PR as it is for IRV.  Of course, as I 
have already said, it makes no sense to do that in a
manual count of any IRV or STV-PR election.  And when it comes to the practical 
transfer of ballots in an STV-PR election there is
no problem at all, whether you are dealing with whole vote transfers on an 
exclusion or fractional transfers of a surplus.


  The practicalities of election administration are extremely important 
  and as a returning officer for some elections, I am well aware of 
  that.  But electoral administration must not be allowed to put 
  artificial or convenient limitations on the democratic process.
 
 
 Except in the case of such methods as IRV when the method is 
 not only wholly inconvenient and costly and virtually 
 impossible to hand count understandably and quickly and is 
 also unfair and produces awful outcomes.

IRV and STV-PR are quite easy to count by hand and the procedures and the 
outcomes are widely understood.  They have been doing just
that in Ireland and Malta since 1920, and in Northern Ireland again since 1973. 
 The multi-seat count may take longer than one
plurality count, but that one multi-seat count replaces several plurality 
counts.  And of course, there is no comparison at all in
what is achieved in terms of fair and democratic representation of the voters  
-  which should always be the deciding factor.



 A simpler method to administer is always preferable, other 
 things being equal, to a complex costly method such as IRV, 

But of course, other thing are not equal.  And there are higher priorities in 
achieving democratic representation than cost and
complexity.


 but IRV does not even provide any reason to use it since it 
 fails more fairness criteria 

Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-22 Thread James Gilmour
Abd ul-Rahman Lomax   Sent: Friday, January 22, 2010 5:53 PM
  At 03:57 AM 1/22/2010, James Gilmour wrote:
 This
 second set of rules are those that prescribe the transfer of votes
 to the bitter end, i.e. even after the winners have all been
 determined.  Under this rule a ballot marked A would be treated 
 differently from a ballot marked AB: at the last possible
 transfer, the A ballot would become 'non-transferable 
 (exhausted)', but the AB ballot would be transferred to A.
 
 You mean transferred to B, of course.

Apologies - my example was incomplete.  To illustrate this stupid rule 
properly, I should have posited two candidates, A and B, (or
just two left after all others have been eliminated), with A the winner.  Then 
consider two ballots, one marked B and the other
marked BA.  In the last round of a count under the to the bitter end 
transfer rule, the ballot marked B would be
'non-transferrable (exhausted)', but the vote on the BA ballot would be 
transferred to A.  It is illogical to treat these ballots
differently in an STV (contingency choice) election and it offends the 
underlying concepts of 'Later No Harm' to transfer the BA
ballot to A.


 This second rule is, of course, a stupid rule but that does not mean
 it has not been implemented in some jurisdictions, including,
 sadly, Scotland.
 
 Not stupid, precisely because of the difference between AB and A. 
 The former is an acceptance of the last listed preference, the latter 
 is not. It makes a difference if a majority is required. Not if it is 
 not, though it might make a difference with some methods. But not IRV.

But my comments were exclusively in the context of STV elections (IRV, STV-PR, 
RCV).


   It is also a highly undesirable rule because it means that my vote
  could, in some circumstances, be transferred to
 the candidate I deliberately ranked last in the lowest possible 
 place, e.g. 12th out of 12 candidates.
 
 Basically, if there are as many ranks as candidates, don't vote for 
 that last one! That's your choice, unless full ranking is required, 
 in which case you *can't* vote the truncated vote and it is 
 irrelevant if it's counted or not.

That's why when running an STV election where we can use write in boxes for 
all preferences, I always provide one fewer preference
box than the number of candidates (as I see you recommended in a later part of  
your post).  But all of our ballots for public
elections have the candidates names printed on them.


Following on from the
 concept of 'Later No Harm' (which underpins the whole of contingency
 voting, as in IRV and STV-PR), it is very important to be able
 to give a voter the absolutely assurance that under no circumstances 
 will her vote ever be transferred to the candidate she has
 ranked 12th out of 12.  Sadly, the stupid transfer to the bitter 
 end rule undermines this.
 
 Only because of voter ignorance, an ignorance which has sometimes 
 been encouraged by activists.

No, not at all.  This is a piece of nonsense that some have introduced into STV 
counting, especially since electronic counting
became available.  It does not feature in any of the long-established versions 
of STV counting rules promoted in the UK.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2637 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Thursday, January 21, 2010 6:49 AM
 but breaking it down to piles regarding every conceivable permutation  
 of candidate preference is *still* breaking it down to a finite  
 number of piles.  for 3 candidates, that number is 9.  if you or  
 Kathy say it's 15, then you're wrong (and it's your slip that's  
 showing).  for 4 candidates the number of necessary piles is 
 40.
  for  N candidates, the number of piles necessary, P(N) is
 
 N-1
  P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=1
 
 not
 
 N-1
  P(N) = SUM{ N!/n! }
 n=0

I do not intend to comment on your formula, but I calculate the numbers of 
possible unique preference profiles for increasing
numbers of candidates (N) as follows:

N   Unique Preference Profiles
2   4
3   15
4   64
5   325
6   1,956
7   13,699
8   109,600
9   986,409
10  9,864,100
11  108,505,111
12  1,302,061,344
13  16,926,797,485
14  236,975,164,804
15  3,554,627,472,075
16  56,874,039,553,216
17  966,858,672,404,689
18  17,403,456,103,284,400
19  330,665,665,962,404,000
20  6,613,313,319,248,080,000


Where there are large numbers of candidates, the maximum possible number of 
unique preference profiles will be limited by the number
of voters.  Thus if there are 10,000 valid votes and 12 candidates, the maximum 
possible number of preference profiles would be
10,000 and not 1,302,061,344.

In practice the actual number of preference profiles would be even lower, as 
significant numbers of voters would record identical
patterns of preferences.  Thus in the Meath constituency for the Dáil Éireann 
election in 2002 with 14 candidates (236,975,164,804
possibilities), there were 64,081 valid votes, but only 25,101 unique 
preference profiles.


The Minneapolis STV (RCV) ballots were all hand sorted to unique preference 
profiles for each precinct and hand counted.  This was
unnecessary but feasible as the voters could not record more than three 
preferences (rankings), no matter the numbers of candidates.
I understand the full preference profiles, probably at precinct level, will be 
published on the City website, but they are not there
yet.

James Gilmour



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2636 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
07:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV vs Plurality (back to the pile count controversy)

2010-01-21 Thread James Gilmour
  N   Unique Preference Profiles
  2   4
  3   15
 ...
 
 then your calculation is mistaken.  the fact that you ostensibly need  
 4 piles when there are only two candidates should serve as a clue.
 

If there are two candidates, A and B, then the possible unique preference 
profiles are: 
A   
B   
A  B
B  A

Anything that does not conform to this is an incorrect use of the term 
preference profile.

James Gilmour




No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.730 / Virus Database: 271.1.1/2636 - Release Date: 01/21/10 
07:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Anyone got a good analysis on limitations of approval andrange voting?

2009-11-29 Thread James Gilmour
  Robert Bristow-Johnson wrote (9 Nov 2009):
 
  Of course IRV, Condorcet, and Borda use different methods  to tabulate 
  the votes and select the winner and my opinion is that IRV (asset 
  voting, I might call it commodity voting: your vote is a 
  commodity that you transfer according to your preferences) is a 
  kabuki dance of transferred votes.  and there is an *arbitrary* 
  evaluation in the elimination of candidates in the IRV rounds: 2nd- 
  choice votes don't count for shit in deciding who to eliminate (who 
  decided that?  2nd-choice votes are as good as last-choice?  under 
  what meaningful and consistent philosophy was that decided?), then 
  when your candidate is eliminated your 2nd-choice vote counts as much 
  as your 1st-choice.

These statements suggest a misunderstanding of how STV voting works and what 
preferences (US rankings) mean in the STV voting
system.  In all STV elections, the preferences are contingency choices.  Your 
vote is transferred to your second choice only in the
event that your first choice cannot secure election or does not need you 
support to secure election.

This is most easily seen in single-winner STV elections (US = IRV), where the 
sequence of rounds is exactly analogous to the
sequence of rounds in an exhaustive ballot (eliminating one candidate at a time 
in successive ballots).  The only difference is that
in an STV (IRV) election you don't know what all the other voters did in Round 
1 when you come to give your second choice.  So the
preferences (= contingency choices) marked on an STV ballot are quite different 
from the preferences marked on, for example, a Borda
ballot where some attempt will be made to use all of the information 
simultaneously.

The same applies to STV multi-winner elections (STV-PR), though the connection 
is not so obvious in versions of STV that use
fractional transfer values to remove the otherwise unavoidable element of 
chance.  However, the contingency choice nature of the
STV-PR preferences is obvious in those versions of STV-PR that use whole vote 
transfers, e.g. Cambridge MA and the Dáil Éireann.  It
is even more obvious in Thomas Hill's original application of STV-PR when the 
boys formed lines in the schoolyard to show their
support for the various candidates.

These STV preferences are all quite clearly contingency choices and they should 
not be interpreted in any other way.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.86/2533 - Release Date: 11/28/09 
19:34:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV is best method meeting 'later no harm'?

2009-11-26 Thread James Gilmour
  sepp...@alumni.caltech.edu wrote:
  By the way, if my understanding is correct, IRV is not Single 
  Transferable Vote (STV), the single-winner voting method used in 
  Australia  Ireland. IRV severely limits the number of candidates each 
  voter can rank (to 3, if my understanding is correct) whereas STV 
  allows (or requires) each voter to rank every candidate.  STV 
  satisfies LNH, and many people may consider it to be somewhat better 
  than IRV. (STV facilitates greater competition and less spoiling, 
  especially if candidates are permitted to withdraw after  the votes are 
  cast.)

 Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Thursday, November 26, 2009 10:15 PM
 IRV is STV(1,n), i.e. single winner IRV. What you describe sounds like 
 FairVote's RCV, which was limited to three ranks to make it work on SF's 
 machinery.

This second statement is also wrong.  RCV = Ranked Choice Voting, which is 
exactly the same as STV = Single Transferable
Vote.  Both RCV and STV can be used in single-winner and multiple-winner 
elections.  It has become common in the USA (note, in the
USA) to use the term IRV (= Instant Runoff Voting) when the RCV=STV voting 
system is applied to a single-winner election.

In none of these voting systems, under any of these names, is there any 
restriction on the number of preferences (= rankings in
the USA) that a voter can mark.  In some RCV=STV or IRV elections in the USA 
there have, however, been limitations imposed by the
voting METHOD that has been used.  For example, in the recent RCV elections in 
Minneapolis (mostly single-winner, two
multiple-winner), there was a requirement to use mark-sense ballots (fill in 
the oval) which were designed to record only the
first three rankings because the certified machines that had to be used to 
provide the close-of-poll precinct counts could not count
more than three rankings (three columns).  This artificial (and undesirable) 
restriction is not implicit in the voting system, nor
is there any such restriction in the Minneapolis City Ordinance that prescribes 
the RCV=STV rules for these elections.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.81/2524 - Release Date: 11/24/09 
19:37:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV - the transferrable part is OK (fair), the sequential round elimination is not

2009-11-03 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Tuesday, November 03, 2009 3:27 PM
  Juho wrote:
  If one really wants a two-party system and doesn't want voters to  change
  that fact then one could ban third parties and accept only two. That 
  would solve the spoiler problem :-). 
 Who is this one? Since that one is at odds with the voters, 
 that's not very democratic, is it?
 
 I guess that one democratic way of doing it would be to have the 
 question itself posed to the voters, but with a suitable low-pass filter 
 (e.g. supermajority required to change it, or a majority over a long 
 time); though then I think it'd be better just to have the 
 filter on the decision process itself.

Why in any country that would merit the description democracy would you want 
to impose a two-party system when the votes of the
voters showed that was not what they wanted?

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.47/2478 - Release Date: 11/03/09 
07:36:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV - the transferrable part is OK (fair), the sequential round elimination is not

2009-11-03 Thread James Gilmour
Kristofer Munsterhjelm   Sent: Tuesday, November 03, 2009 4:34 PM
  James Gilmour wrote:
  Why in any country that would merit the description democracy would 
  you want to impose a two-party system when the votes of the voters 
  showed that was not what they wanted?
 
 That is my question, too. 

Maybe what the two-party advocates really want is guaranteed single-party 
majority government.  If that IS what they want, there
is a VERY simple and effective electoral solution.  If no party wins an 
absolute majority of the votes and seats, give 55% of the
seats to the party that wins the largest number of votes and divide the 
remaining seats among the other parties in proportion to the
their shares of the votes.

It has been done and it works.  Importantly, it's honest.  It sets out clearly 
what is considered to be the over-riding electoral
criterion and it fulfils it.  In the UK we suffer from a lot of nonsense about 
the desirability of single-party majority government
and even worse nonsense about the importance of FPTP in securing that.  In 
fact, in two of the most critical elections since 1945,
when the government of the day (one Labour, one Conservative) was seeking a 
renewed mandate for the continuation of its policies,
FPTP elected the wrong government. In both cases the outgoing government won 
the referendum on its policies (votes) and lost the
election (seats).

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.47/2478 - Release Date: 11/03/09 
07:36:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV - the transferrable part is OK (fair), the sequential round elimination is not

2009-11-02 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Monday, November 02, 2009 1:20 PM
 Vote-splitting does mean less proportional 
 representation using STV if more candidates run relative to 
 some groups' constituency share compared to other groups.  

Must be some misunderstanding here.  Because the surplus votes of elected 
candidates and the votes of eliminated candidates are
transferable, the votes will progressively concentrate onto the appropriate 
number of candidates to represent each group
proportionately.


 That and all STV's other extreme flaws is why any of the 
 other better proportional systems are more proportional and 
 also better in a host of other ways.

Proportionality is dependent solely on district magnitude.  For the same 
district magnitude, STV-PR is as proportional as any other
PR voting system  -  no more, but no less.

Extreme flaws and better both require definition and exposition.

For many voters, the ability to rank all the candidates freely on any basis 
whatsoever makes STV-PR better than any other PR
voting system.  One reason why these voters consider that better is the 
effects it can have on the relationships between the
elected members and the local voters, between the elected members and their 
parties, and between the elected assembly and the
executive, especially where the executive is based within the assembly (as in 
parliamentary system).  These political effects
(beyond simple PR) are important considerations, especially from the voters' 
perspective.

James Gilmour



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.42/2473 - Release Date: 10/31/09 
21:14:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] (no subject) STV transfer rules

2009-11-02 Thread James Gilmour
robert bristow-johnson   Sent: Monday, November 02, 2009 5:44 PM
 whose *ballot* gets their vote transferred?  it shouldn't matter in  
 which order the counting is.  if my ballot is needed to give the  
 candidate what he needs, and your ballot isn't needed, then you got  
 to influence the election of your next choice, but I did not.  that  
 can't be fair.

Opinions differ on the importance of this feature  -  as can be seen from the 
continued acceptance in some jurisdictions of STV
rules that treat ballots differently in this way.

But if this feature is important in your assessment of fairness, then you 
could use either the WIGM (Weighted inclusive Gregory
Method) version of STV-PR as implemented for the Scottish Local Government 
elections or Meek STV.  In both of these STV-PR versions
ALL of the candidate's ballots are transferred when any transfer of votes has 
to be made.  Then there is no discrimination of the
kind you describe between these voters.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.42/2473 - Release Date: 10/31/09 
21:14:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV - the transferrable part is OK (fair), the sequential round elimination is not

2009-11-02 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank   Sent: Monday, November 02, 2009 9:41 PM
  To harp on California again: we have 53 Congressional districts, all (of
  course) single-seat FPTP. The distribution of Democratic and Republican
  seats is surprisingly close to representing state party registration.
 
  Yes, FPTP in single-seat districts is statistically proportional, but 
  of course it very strongly favours large parties. This is thus 
  proportional in some sense but doesn't fit well in my definition above 
  since deviation from full proportionality (that would allow also 
  smaller groups to survive) is much larger than what would be 
  necessary.
 
 That is a surprising election result.
 Did they intentionally gerrymander it to work that way?
 Normally, with impartial districting, the result isn't actually proportional.
 Normally, the larger party will get more seats than it is entitled to.

As I have written several times previously, the results of FPTP elections in 
the USA are the ones that are anomalous because the US
results are much more proportional and there are fewer minority members than 
for FPTP elections in most other countries that use
FPTP (e.g. UK, Canada).  Successful incumbent gerrymandering in the US is 
probably the main factor in producing these anomalous
results.  The holding primary elections may also be a contributing factor.


 If you have 60% of the votes, and your supporters are spread 
 randomly, then it is pretty sure than you will have, say 
 55-65% of the votes in every district.

Not necessarily so.  In many countries there are clear urban-rural differences 
in support for different political parties.  In many
cities there are similar clear differences between poorer inner city areas and 
more prosperous suburbs. In these circumstances (e.g.
UK), FPTP produces electoral deserts where one party or another appears to 
have no support at all because it wins no seats.  But
the votes tell a different story.  These distortions of representation have 
dangerous political effects on government policy as the
.government party has little or no representation from one area or the other.


 This amplification like effect leads to more stable 
 governments (which is argued to be a good thing for 
 parliamentary systems).

Such governments are stable only in that they have a large overall majority 
as a result of the defective FPTP voting system.
There is no real stability because at the next election the distortion may go 
the other way.  Then you have reversal of policy and
no stability at all.  Look at the political history of the UK from 1945 for a 
prime example of such instability with severely
detrimental effects on the country in almost every branch of policy: economic, 
social, educational, health, etc, etc.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.44/2475 - Release Date: 11/01/09 
19:39:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] (no subject)

2009-11-01 Thread James Gilmour
Anthony O'Neal   Sent: Sunday, November 01, 2009 7:12 AM
 I don't necessarily think that STV is better than an open party list 
 system.  

I think STV-PR is better than open-list party-list PR in three ways.

Firstly, STV-PR can be used in all public elections, including those that are 
non-partisan.
Secondly, STV-PR can deliver proportionality within individual political 
parties, where most open-list party-list systems will not.
Thirdly, and rather more politically, STV-PR can shift the balance of power 
away from the parties to the voters, IF the voters
decide to make than happen.


 But I'm a political realist, and I think that STV is the system 
 that would be easiest to implement in America.  With our loose coalition 
 Democrat and Republican parties, and our large base of independents, 
 people are too used to voting for the person and not the party to widely 
 accept a system that forces voting for a party.  Even if they do have a 
 large say in said party.

There are two other reasons why STV-PR might be the easiest to implement in 
situations where voters are used to voting in
single-member districts (the appalling British legacy!).  First is the simple 
practically of devising suitable STV multi-member
electoral districts based on existing, recognised communities.  Second is the 
voters' desire for a realistic element of local
representation as well as for broad proportionality.


 STV is proportional if people vote by party.  
 It is also proportional if people vote by eye color. 

Yes, and need not be either or  -  it can be both and.  The voters can rank 
by party and then by eye colour.  Or the voters can
rank by eye colour and then by party.  With STV-PR the voters are free to base 
their rankings of the candidates on as many
dimensions as each voter wishes.

 
 It's main problem is that it's complicated as hell to explain, and the 
 opposition at the BC-STV referendum exploited this mercilessly. 

Yes, a great deal can be made of this, and was by the opponents of reform in 
BC, but it need not be so.

To obtain proportional representation we must elect several members together; 
each voter must have only one vote; and that vote must
be transferable.

The STV-PR counting procedure involves five basic steps:
1.  Once the total number of valid ballots has been counted, the minimum number 
of votes a candidate needs to be elected is
calculated - the 'threshold' or 'quota'. (This threshold is equivalent to the 
'absolute majority' in a single-member electoral
district.)
2.  The ballots are sorted according to the first choices (rank #1) marked by 
the voters and the total number of first choice votes
for each candidate is counted.
3.  Any candidate whose vote equals or exceeds the threshold is elected.  If 
any candidate has more votes than the threshold, that
surplus above the threshold is transferred to remaining candidates in 
accordance with the second and later choices on the elected
candidate's ballots.
4.  If after the surpluses have been transferred some seats remain to be 
filled, the candidate with fewest votes is eliminated and
that candidate's votes are transferred in accordance with the second and later 
choices marked on the ballots.
5.  The transfers of votes continue, round by round, until all seats have been 
filled.


Of course, the detailed instructions for the Returning Officer are a little 
more complex than that, but again can be set out quite
simply, depending on the version of STV-PR adopted.  One merit of the version 
of STV-PR used for the local government elections in
Scotland in 2007 was the very simple principles.  All surpluses must be 
transferred, largest first.  Candidates with fewest votes
must be eliminated one at a time.  When any votes are to be transferred, all of 
the candidate's ballots must be transferred.  These
three principles greatly simplified the procedure, the regulations, the 
description and the explanation.  It all becomes
considerably more complicated when you have to make provision for deferring the 
transfer of small surpluses or for batch
eliminations of several candidates together or electing by sub-stages during 
eliminations.


 So the only real solution for proportional advocates seems to be to 
 either find a billionaire willing to support the cause of STV, or to 
 wait 100 years until Americas increasing polarization makes partisan 
 voting seems not seem so obscene.

I wouldn't be so pessimistic.  The more immediate targets should be those city 
councils and local boards that are very obviously
unrepresentative, especially those already elected at large.  Some State 
legislatures might also provide realistic prospects for
reform.  Although elected by FPTP from single-member districts, the US House of 
Representatives is not as unrepresentative as most
assemblies elected in this way around the world (e.g. UK, Canada).  That's 
probably why Federal electoral reform is not higher up
the public agenda in the USA.

James Gilmour

Re: [EM] STV - the transferrable part is OK (fair), the sequential round elimination is not

2009-10-31 Thread James Gilmour
  (PR makes sense in general but I wouldn't deny people
  the right to achieve the political balance using two-party systems if 
  they so want.)
 
  How would this decision be made? Majority rule?
 
  It's not hard to imagine a referendum with that kind of effect. I 
  don't see how you can get away from majority rule; even if we elect a 
  body using PR-STV to vote on the party system, that's still  majority 
  rule (or a super-majority rule with a possibility of no outcome), it's 
  just different people voting in the end.

If you genuinely have a two party system, you have no problem.  The problems 
arise when significant numbers of voters do not vote
for either of the two largest parties, but the politicians of the two largest 
parties want the political system to function as if
there were only two parties and a guaranteed single-party majority after every 
election.

If you believe in representative democracy and believe that the representative 
assemblies in such a democracy (city councils,
state legislatures) should be fairly representative of those who vote, then you 
must be prepared to accept the representation the
voters say they want.  If the voters fall into two main categories, so be it.  
But if the voters are divided among three, four or
five significant groups, so be it, too  -  that's what the voters say they want.

One of the advantages of STV-PR is that it is party-neutral and it allows the 
voters to have a direct influence on party behaviour.
For example, for the first 40 years of STV-PR in Malta the voters elected 
members of 3, 4 or 5 parties to their parliament.  But for
the past 40 years of STV-PR all the members of the Maltese parliament have 
elected from only two parties.  That change was brought
about by the voters because more than two parties still contest the elections.  
So the representation in the parliament could be
different IF the voters wanted that.


 PR-STV was used in quite a few US cities in the first half of the 20C.  
 Mostly, it got repealed when the local majority party realized that  
 they could benefit from majority-take-all voting, and could avoid  
 sharing power by repealing PR.

Big party politics, big business and big media combined in some VERY dirty 
campaigns to dump fair representation of ordinary voters!


 One can imagine establishing a culture of PR where even members of  
 the majority support the idea that others should be represented; this  
 seems to be the case in various places outside the US, and for  
 whatever reason in Cambridge MA. But this has certainly not been the  
 rule in the US.

It may come as shock to many in the USA, but most countries in Europe elect 
their national, regional and local assemblies by some
system of proportional representation.  Rarely are the voters divided into only 
two blocks, so single-party majorities are rare.  In
Europe, it is the UK that is the exception, where despite having a genuine 
multi-party system political system we cling to the
discredited FPTP voting system with single-member districts that artificially 
(and wrongly) manufactures single-party majority
government against the voters' wishes.  Sometimes our governments have 
obscenely large majorities despite having only minority
support among these who voted  -  currently a majority of 66 seats (out of 646) 
with only 35% of the votes.  But that's party
politics!

James Gilmour







No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.39/2469 - Release Date: 10/30/09 
07:52:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV - the transferrable part is OK (fair), the sequential round elimination is not

2009-10-30 Thread James Gilmour
 of proportional representation must be precinct-summable in
 a reasonable fashion

It is well-known that you attach great importance to this, but it is not a 
feature or requirement of public elections in many
countries.  NO public elections in the UK are ever counted at precinct level. 
All the ballots are taken to the relevant counting
centre before the ballot boxes are opened.  And it has been like that for many, 
many decades.  And it is not a source of any problem
or concern.


 and give all voters' votes equal treatment,
 unlike with the current version of IRV/STV being pushed by Fairytale
 Vote which does neither and also in addition does not provide
 proportional representation due to vote-splitting when the number of
 candidates running who represent my interests is too great, or due to
 not enough candidates running in proportion to the voters who share my
 interests.

STV-PR does, in fact, treat all voters and all voters' votes equally.  The 
purpose of the vote being transferable subject only to
limit of the number of candidates or any lower limit imposed by the individual 
voter, is to obtain PR.  Of course, if any political
party or interest group underestimates its likely support among the voters, and 
so nominates too few candidates, it has only itself
to blame.  If you do not nominate the candidates, you cannot win the seats.


 That's why fundamentally the IRV/STV system is a lousy one for
 achieving proportional representation even if it were modified to
 treat all voters equally and be easily manually checked for accuracy.

STV-PR does give PR, of whatever the voters want.


 The party list system works much better for achieving proportional
 representation as long as there is a party representing your
 interests.  It doesn't have to be a party, but could just be that
 each candidate chooses his own list of candidates below him/her to
 pass excess votes down to.

Here you again fail to recognise the essential difference between the party 
list approach and STV-PR.  The two groups of voting
systems have fundamentally different objectives.  They also have different 
political effects.  All party-list systems will, or will
tend to, strengthen the position of the party machines, whereas STV-PR will 
shift the balance of power away from the party machines
and give it to the voters, to whom it belongs.


If all you want politically is PR of registered political parties, a party-list 
PR voting system will give you that.  But if you
have a different, better vision of politics and the police system, you will 
want to empower the voters, and that's what STV-PR could
do.

James Gilmour



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 9.0.698 / Virus Database: 270.14.39/2469 - Release Date: 10/30/09 
07:52:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Holding byelections with PR-STV

2009-09-15 Thread James Gilmour
 On Mon, Sep 14, 2009 at 4:19 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
  The 'count back' procedure with STV-PR provides an alternative 
  approach to the principle of preserving the proportionality determined 
  at the previous main election.  Then the voters would get the 
  proportionality they would have got at the main election had the 
  member who caused the casual vacancy not stood at the main election.  
  Where the elections are partisan, this approach would provide an 
  incentive for the political parties to nominate more candidates that 
  the numbers of seats they expected to win, so that they would have one 
  or more spares.  In Malta the main parties take this to extremes, as 
  they both have sometimes nominated 12 candidates in some 5-member 
  districts.

 Raph Frank   Sent: Monday, September 14, 2009 5:22 PM
 I think, in the end, this is probably the best plan.  The 
 spares give an added bonus that voters get more choice.

Yes, this would be a very good side-effect of adopting the 'count back' 
procedure  -  and it's one (hidden) reason why some of us
are keen to see it introduced in Scotland.


 Under Meek, would this just be a matter of setting the 
 resigning candidate's keep value to zero?

Depending on the program you use, you don't even need to do that.  OpenSTV and 
some of the private UK versions of Meek STV have a
provision for withdrawn candidates.  You just set the number code for the 
'withdrawn' candidate to its negative value (e.g. 2
becomes -2) in the second row of the BLT file and the program does the rest, 
passing over that candidate as though s/he had never
stood, I presume by setting a zero keep value at the beginning. (see Ballots 
Menu in OpenSTV Manual at
http://www.openstv.org/manual)

New Zealand is, so far as I know, the only country that uses Meek STV for 
public elections.  They do not appear to have any
provision for 'withdrawn candidates'.  They do allow multiple candidacies for 
specified hierarchies of elections, e.g. mayor
(first), territory (second), community (third).  So if a candidate is elected 
as mayor and also as a territory council member, they
declare an exceptional vacancy for the territory council and fill it 
separately.  They don't seem to use the 'withdrawn' feature  -
maybe it isn't programmed into their version of Meek STV.

In UK public elections candidates are not allowed to withdraw once the deadline 
for nominations has passed.  If a candidate dies
after the close of nominations but before the formal declaration of the result, 
the whole election for that constituency or ward is
declared void and a new election must be held within a specified number of days.


 Setting a candidate's keep value to zero should only increase 
 the vote totals of all the other candidates.  Thus, all 
 elected candidates would stay elected and Meek's method never 
 changes the keep values to eliminate an elected candidate.

The first statement seems logical, but I don't know about the second statement. 
 I don't understand how an elected candidate could
be eliminated  -  sounds like a contradiction of terms. 


 The problem would be that setting an eliminated candidate's 
 keep value back to 1 could bring an elected candidate below 
 the quota.  One option would be to set all running 
 candidates at the highest possible keep value such that all 
 elected candidates have more than a quota worth of votes.

I don't know what any of this means as I am not sufficiently familiar with the 
inner workings of Meek STV.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.409 / Virus Database: 270.13.96/2369 - Release Date: 09/14/09 
17:52:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Holding byelections with PR-STV

2009-09-14 Thread James Gilmour
-party control in local government.  This illogical application of the 
by-election approach to filling casual vacancies has
delighted the SNP but sent shockwaves through the Labour Party.

James Gilmour






No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.409 / Virus Database: 270.13.94/2367 - Release Date: 09/14/09 
05:51:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Election-Methods Digest, Vol 62, Issue 10 - Explaining PR-STV

2009-08-31 Thread James Gilmour
I have changed the subject to make it clear and to link it again to the related 
posts  - apologies for not doing that on my previous
post.

What you describe below is not a feature of the SNTV voting system but the 
careful strategic and tactical manipulation of the voting
system to obtain a PR outcome.  But even then, it is only PR of the registered 
political parties.  Iif the voters expressed their
true wishes about the candidates, PR of the parties would probably not be 
obtained.

So I think my statement was a fair one.

James


Kristofer Munsterhjelm  Sent: Monday, August 31, 2009 7:17 AM
 James Gilmour wrote:
  It is extremely important to refer to STV as the SINGLE Transferable 
  Vote, because each voter must have only one vote to ensure PR. This 
  distinguishes STV from all multiple vote systems, like 
  Multi-Member-FPTP or the Cumulative Vote.  It is also important to 
  emphasise the Single TRANSFERABLE Vote, because PR cannot be obtained 
  (except by chance) if that single vote is not transferable (as in the 
  Single Non-Transferable Vote).
 
 That's not completely true. Some methods that don't use transferable 
 votes have a strategy equilibrium where there's PR. Consider, for 
 instance, SNTV (you get one vote, the n best wins), under party control. 
   If a given party fields too many candidates, their votes are spread 
 too thin and they lose. If the party fields too few candidates, they 
 miss some seats they could otherwise have acquired. Thus each party 
 fields a number of candidates proportional to that party's support, and 
 instructs the people to vote randomly for one of the party' candidates 
 (so as to spread the votes evenly).
 
 You may argue that the random part of the allocation constitutes chance, 
 but it doesn't have to. When Taiwan was using the SNTV, one of the 
 parties instructed the voters to decide which candidate to vote for 
 according to the voter's birthday. That's uniform but it's not random 
 (since the birthday remains the same).
 
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.409 / Virus Database: 270.13.72/2337 - Release Date: 08/31/09 
05:50:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Redistricting, now with racial demographics

2009-07-18 Thread James Gilmour
If one of the requirements is to secure representation within a state for the 
significant (racial) minorities within that state,
would it not make much more sense to start with a voting system that had such 
an objective rather than engage in deliberate
distortion of district boundaries in an attempt to overcome the deficiencies of 
a voting system designed for a completely different
purpose?

James Gilmour


Brian Olson   Sent: Saturday, July 18, 2009 2:39 PM
 As this isn't something I really want it's going to be hard to get  
 motivated to work it out.
 That said I think the way to go about it is to make unbiased districts  
 by my current district, then pick one district with the highest  
 proportion of the desired minority to elevate and adjust all the  
 districts until that one has a majority of the desired minority.  
 Repeat one district at a time until there are enough (some states  
 require two or three I think).
 
  On Jul 16, 2009, at 6:46 PM, Raph Frank wrote:
  Are you considering updating the algorithm to include majority
  minority districts?
 
  This would potentially decrease the legal issues with using it for  
  districting.


Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.392 / Virus Database: 270.13.19/2245 - Release Date: 07/18/09 
05:57:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Forced strictly-dishonest strategy is common inSchulze-beatpaths voting

2009-06-14 Thread James Gilmour
Jan Kok   Sent: Sunday, June 14, 2009 12:50 AM
  Warren wrote:
  I have news for you.   The concept of strategic voting is entirely 
  about caring more about  vanishingly small gains in utility 
  than about  honesty.
 
 It's not vanishingly small if you think about it from a team 
 perspective.

If you are not referring to any particular voting system, spectacular support 
for Jan's view is available from the 1997 UK General
Election (FPTP in SMDs).  Large numbers of supporters of several parties voted 
insincerely to make sure that Conservative MPs were
unseated throughout Scotland and Wales.  Despite having significant voting 
support in both countries, the Conservatives did not win
a single seat in either Scotland or Wales.  That was the direct result of well 
organised, and very effective, cross-party Tory-free
Scotland  and Tory-free Wales tactical voting campaigns.

Incidentally, we call this tactical voting, when the voter votes insincerely 
in response to the local political situation.  We use
strategic voting for situations where they vote insincerely in response to 
some feature of the voting system itself.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.364 / Virus Database: 270.12.68/2175 - Release Date: 06/14/09 
05:53:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] simple definition of Schulze method?

2009-06-04 Thread James Gilmour
 2009/6/4 James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk
 Markus, UK electors have no hope of understanding that 
 question at all after any campaign, never mind not instantly. 
  And of those who would vote, large numbers would go to vote 
 with very little prior information.
 
 Just two weeks before polling day for the 2007 elections to 
 the Scottish Parliament ONLY ONE-THIRD of electors were able 
 to say correctly which political parties had ministers in the 
 Scottish Executive that had been running the country for the 
 previous four years.  19% said they did not know, and the 
 rest gave wrong answers.  The level of political knowledge 
 among the electors must not be over-estimated  -  it is 
 almost certainly a lot lower than most of us would like to 
 think.  And I suspect Scotland and the UK are not unique in that.

 -Original Message-
 From: Árpád Magosányi [mailto:mag...@rabic.org] 
 This is the people are dumb reasoning, which I believe is 
 false. Irish voters needed a year of brainwash to came close 
 to change their opinion on EU constitution. We cannot be 
 grateful to them enough for that no. After that you can 
 tell me anything, I will know that they know what they are 
 doing. As Chomsky said, most of us are able to speak 
 fluently, so we should be able to understand anything. Our 
 political system is built in a way which discourages people 
 to pay attention?  People are feed with bullshit instead of 
 the real questions? These are the problems, not the people.

I am sorry but you cannot dismiss the facts in this way.  We are constantly 
told that purpose of any election is to give the voters
the opportunity to Kick the rascals out.  In political-science-speak, the 
most salient feature of any election is which party or
parties form the current government.  Then the voters can decide whether they 
want to keep that government or kick that government
out.  But if you are going to do that in any sensible way when you cast your 
vote, you first need to know which party or parties
form the current government.  In Scotland in the middle of April 2007, just two 
weeks before polling day, after three weeks of the
intensive election campaign, and after many months of less intensive 
campaigning (as our elections are held on fixed dates), only
ONE-THIRD of electors could correctly identify the parties in the government.  
Even if they knew nothing else about politics, surely
they would know that  - the most salient feature of the election?  But NO, the 
hard evidence is that they did not, and to a
staggering extent.

Of course, the challenge is to those who have a message they want to get 
across.  But in devising ways to get the message across, I
say again, do not over-estimate the political knowledge or understanding of the 
electors.  Do not take my word for that  -  look at
the evidence quoted from the SES survey of 1,871 electors (a very large survey 
by all normal standards).  And similarly, do not
over-estimate the average reading age  -  even in literate countries the 
average reading age is much lower then you might think or
like to think.  Harsh, unpleasant realities, but realities nonetheless.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.339 / Virus Database: 270.12.53/2154 - Release Date: 06/04/09 
05:53:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Good news - BC voters reject STV

2009-05-15 Thread James Gilmour
Anthony O'Neal   Sent: Friday, May 15, 2009 7:04 PM
 This is sad news, no matter what the anti-STV fanatics say.  STV had 
 flaws, it's still a far better system than FPP.  The anti-STV campaign 
 put out a huge misinformation campaign which did nothing but say Hey 
 look at how complicated STV is?  AN ALGORITHM FOR VOTING!  
 WHY EVEN HAVE VOTERS! 

Anthony, it was far worse than that  -  lots of newspaper articles, editorials 
and letters contained outright LIES.  Like for
example, STV would transfer my vote to someone whose election I oppose.  That 
can never happen with STV, but it didn't stop the
lies being spread.


 It was stupid, and generations later BC is going to regret 
 what they passed up.

Yes, indeed, and BC is going to regret it for the next two decades until they 
get the chance to consider electoral reform again.
For many decades, the election results from Canada and its Provinces have shown 
everything that is wrong with FPTP in single-member
districts.

Along with the lies, there was some misinformation from the misinformed.  And 
sadly, some who should know better, just do not begin
to understand how a contingency voting system like STV really works.  Or maybe 
they had a political agenda for opposing reform and
just wanted to hide behind their misrepresentations of STV.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.329 / Virus Database: 270.12.30/2115 - Release Date: 05/14/09 
17:54:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] British Colombia considering change to STV

2009-05-10 Thread James Gilmour
Apologies if you have already seen this message, but it appears to have got the 
website but has not been posted out  -  at least it
never came to me, nor did Kristofer's message that followed it on a completely 
different topic. 
JG  



Graham Bignell   Sent: Thursday, May 07, 2009 4:10 PM
 This is one of the more amusing editorials about the proposal...

http://network.nationalpost.com/np/blogs/fullcomment/archive/2009/05/07/national-post-editorial-board-first-egghead-past-the-post-wi
ns-b-c-s-referendum.aspx
 
 One sign that a society is running out of real problems is
 that bored upper-middle-class types start inventing phony 
 ones. Thus do we periodically get initiatives aimed at 
 replacing our perfectly functional first-past-the-post 
 electoral system with some hybrid alternative that few 
 understand or support. In Ontario, this alternative - soundly 
 rejected at the polls in 2007 - was called mixed-member 
 proportional representation. In British Columbia, it's called 
 the Single Transferable Vote.

It may be amusing to those not directly involved, but the sneering 
intellectual who wrote that editorial could hardly have got it
more wrong.  Far from being a phony problem, reform of a defective voting 
system is fundamental to the health of representative
democracy.  The voting system defines and determines the relationship between 
the voters and the elected representatives.  That in
turn, determines the relationship between the elected members and their 
parties, and it also determines the relationship between the
elected members in the assembly (city council, state legislature, parliament) 
and the executive (government).

The voting system determines the balance of power and accountability of the 
elected members as between the voters and the political
parties that nominate most of the candidates.  Some voting systems make the 
elected members much more accountable to their parties
than to their voters.  Some other voting systems shift that balance, to a 
greater or lesser extent, in favour of the voters.
Correcting that balance is a real problem for society, not a phony one.  Those 
who pretend otherwise have often got partisan reasons
for opposing reform and trying to obscure this reality.

If it were not so serious, it would certainly be amusing to see 
first-past-the-post described as perfectly functional.  I can only
presume that the writer of that editorial had not looked at the results of the 
FPTP elections in British Columbia or Canada over the
years.  BC, the other Canadian Provinces and Canada federally, all operate what 
is supposed to be (claimed to be) a representative
democracy.  So the first requirement of the voting system is to ensure that 
the various elected assemblies are properly
representative of those who voted.  On that, FPTP signally fails to deliver.  
And of course, in partisan elections, FPTP also makes
the elected members much more accountable to their parties than to the local 
voters.

James Gilmour




Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] British Colombia considering change to STV

2009-05-09 Thread James Gilmour
Graham Bignell   Sent: Thursday, May 07, 2009 4:10 PM
 This is one of the more amusing editorials about the proposal... 

http://network.nationalpost.com/np/blogs/fullcomment/archive/2009/05/07/national-post-editorial-board-first-egghead-past-the-post-wi
ns-b-c-s-referendum.aspx
 
 One sign that a society is running out of real problems is 
 that bored upper-middle-class types start inventing phony 
 ones. Thus do we periodically get initiatives aimed at 
 replacing our perfectly functional first-past-the-post 
 electoral system with some hybrid alternative that few 
 understand or support. In Ontario, this alternative — soundly 
 rejected at the polls in 2007 — was called mixed-member 
 proportional representation. In British Columbia, it’s called 
 the “Single Transferable Vote.”

It may be amusing to those not directly involved, but the sneering 
intellectual who wrote that editorial could hardly have got it
more wrong.  Far from being a phony problem, reform of a defective voting 
system is fundamental to the health of representative
democracy.  The voting system defines and determines the relationship between 
the voters and the elected representatives.  That in
turn, determines the relationship between the elected members and their 
parties, and it also determines the relationship between the
elected members in the assembly (city council, state legislature, parliament) 
and the executive (government).

The voting system determines the balance of power and accountability of the 
elected members as between the voters and the political
parties that nominate most of the candidates.  Some voting systems make the 
elected members much more accountable to their parties
than to their voters.  Some other voting systems shift that balance, to a 
greater or lesser extent, in favour of the voters.
Correcting that balance is a real problem for society, not a phony one.  Those 
who pretend otherwise have often got partisan reasons
for opposing reform and trying to obscure this reality.

If it were not so serious, it would certainly be amusing to see 
first-past-the-post described as perfectly functional.  I can only
presume that the writer of that editorial had not looked at the results of the 
FPTP elections in British Columbia or Canada over the
years.  BC, the other Canadian Provinces and Canada federally, all operate what 
is supposed to be (claimed to be) a representative
democracy.  So the first requirement of the voting system is to ensure that 
the various elected assemblies are properly
representative of those who voted.  On that, FPTP signally fails to deliver.  
And of course, in partisan elections, FPTP also makes
the elected members much more accountable to their parties than to the local 
voters.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.325 / Virus Database: 270.12.22/2105 - Release Date: 05/08/09 
11:43:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] British Colombia considering change to STV

2009-05-03 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank   Sent: Sunday, May 03, 2009 1:51 AM
 I think a candidate list system is better though as it allows 
 more general inheritance ordering.  Ofc, it is always going 
 to be a tradeoff between precision and complexity (both for 
 the count and for the voter).
 
 Closed party list
 Open party list
 Tree based lists
 Candidate list
 PR-STV
 
 All, except PR-STV could be handled at the national level.
 Party list would allow a much smaller ballot.
 The 3 middle options would use the same pick one candidate ballot.

This analysis is simplistic and completely ignores the fundamental 
philosophical divide between voting systems designed to deliver
PR of registered political PARTIES and voting systems designed to deliver PR of 
what the VOTERS want (as expressed by the voters'
responses to the candidates who have offered themselves for election).  This is 
a matter of fundamental political philosophy - which
route you take determines the relationships between the elected members and the 
voters, between the elected members and their
parties, and between the elected members in the parliament and the executive 
(government).  Where should power lie - in the parties
or with the voters?  To whom should the elected members be really accountable - 
to the their parties or to their voters?

In some political cultures, having the political system centred around the 
political parties is not an issue (or does not appear to
be an issue) and party list PR systems are common such countries.  But other 
political cultures do not want the political system
centred on the political parties, although the parties are an essential part of 
the political system.  Some such countries do not
like party list PR (even if an unrepresentative government has forced it on 
them!!).

So the questions that must be answered first are not about the degree of 
proportionality or the complexity of the ballot, or
even the size of the districts, but about what the voting system is intended 
to achieve in terms of representation.  Some will
be happy to go the party list route, but many others are not.  Lumping all the 
multi-member voting system together as though there
were all just different flavours of ice-cream is a flawed approach and it is 
unhelpful in the debate about how best to go forward in
different political cultures.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.287 / Virus Database: 270.12.15/2093 - Release Date: 05/02/09 
14:23:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] British Colombia considering change to STV

2009-05-02 Thread James Gilmour
 Juho Laatu Sent: Saturday, May 02, 2009 11:33 PM

  In Ireland, the constitution requires at least 3 per constituency and
  over time the average number of seats per constituency is being
  reduced.  It is currently illegal (by statutory law) for
  constituencies to have more than 5 seats.  For the upcoming EU
  elections, Ireland's 12 seats are being returned from all 3
  seat constituencies.
 
 It practice that seems to set the limits
 to max 4 and min 2 parties/groupings per
 constituency represented in the Dáil. 
 http://en.wikipedia.org/wiki/Members_of_the_30th_D%C3%A1il

When the Dáil was created, Ireland elected 120 members from 26 constituencies 
(electoral districts) returning from 4 to 8 (YES, 8)
members (average district magnitude was 4.62).  Ireland's politicians divided 
the larger constituencies (especially in 1973)
because they thought it would favour their re-election, so that the Dáil now 
has 166 members elected form 42 constituencies (average
DM = 3.95).


   One could also develop rules that would
   make the system more proportional at the
   country level
  
  I think care needs to be taken here, as votes for a
  candidate are not necessarily the same as votes for a party.
  (The tree system can resolve this).

This issue has been raised again in Malta, and there was an interesting paper 
on possible solutions in the January 2009 issue of
Voting matters: 
  http://www.votingmatters.org.uk/ISSUE26/I26P1.pdf


 Yes. One could try to limit the number of
 candidates to keep voting easy from the
 voter point of view and to keep the size
 of the ballots sheets manageable. 

But be aware that in Malta, where they fill casual vacancies by counting the 
original ballots again, it is not uncommon for the two
main parties to nominate up to 12 candidates for some of the 5-member electoral 
districts.  Another feature of election law in Malta
that results in longer lists of candidates is that they allow one person to be 
nominated in several electoral districts.  If elected
in more than one district, that candidate can decide which district to 
represent, when there would be an instant by-election to fill
the casual vacancy so caused (when the ballots would be counted again).


  I think a mix of 5+ seater PR-STV seats and a quality national level
  system (say candidate list or tree list) might be a good compromise.

See also the article in Voting matters, linked above.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.287 / Virus Database: 270.12.13/2091 - Release Date: 05/01/09 
17:52:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] PR-STV with approval based elimination

2009-05-01 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank   Sent: Thursday, April 30, 2009 6:33 PM
 Also, I think later no harm basically means won't 
 compromise.  I am not sure that it is even a desirable 
 criterion for a method to have and think that the fact that a 
 method that doesn't meet later no harm is a not major issue.

 I don't think support for Later No Harm means won't compromise.  If you 
impose a social choice interpretation on the rankings on
a ballot, you would probably consider LNH to be undesirable, but of course, 
the rankings on an STV ballot are not social choice
scores and should not be interpreted in that way.

One problem with abandoning LNH is that it opens the way for strategic voting, 
that is, when a voter ranks the candidates in some
order other than the sincere 'first to last' order of preference because the 
voter knows that some feature of the voting system will
enhance the changes of the real high preferences being elected if the rankings 
marked on the ballot are distorted in a particular
way.

It is my experience when explaining voting systems to ordinary electors that 
they do consider LNH to be important.  They not want a
voting system in which marking their second choice would count against the 
election of their first choice.  And of course, STV
ensures that that cannot happen.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.5.287 / Virus Database: 270.12.12/2090 - Release Date: 05/01/09 
06:17:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV proponents figure out how to make IRV precinct-summable

2009-03-18 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank  Sent: Wednesday, March 18, 2009 12:56 PM
 Adb's ballot imaging idea takes this to the extreme.  With 
 pattern recognition software, you could support virtually any 
 voting method.
 
 The counting process would just produce a list of numbers 
 corresponding to each ballot.
 
 In its most simple form, you would just need a pattern 
 recognition program that can recognise the numbers 0 to 9 and 
 maybe also the letter X (for place an X next to your 
 favourite candidate).
 
 As long as the ballots are designed to make this easy, it 
 shouldn't be that difficult a task.  There would be a box 
 provided for each number that the voter fills in.
 
 I wrote some software that is a basic attempt at this.  
 However, it only gives 70% ish accuracy.
 
 See:
 
 http://groups.yahoo.com/group/RangeVoting/files/Ballot%20image/
 
 The circles are used to align the image and the black 
 rectangle at the top is used to work out where the top of the 
 ballot is.
 
 I think if there was demand, it should be possible to make 
 this software much more accurate, since it doesn't have to 
 worry about most of the complexities of handwriting 
 recognition.  It wouldn't have to separate out letters as 
 each 'box' would only contain one number and there are only 
 10 possibilities.  Also, since each box would be in a known 
 position on the page, it would be able to figure out where 
 each letter is located.

I'm afraid there is a little more involved that your description would suggest 
because real voters do things you might never expect.
But it has all already been done for public elections.  Just one example of 
which I have some knowledge.  In May 2007 in Scotland
two different elections were held on the same day.  In the MMP elections 
(Scottish Parliament) the two votes were recorded by Xs
in separate columns on a combined ballot sheet.  In the STV-PR elections (local 
government - 32 councils) the preferential votes
were recorded by 1, 2, 3 etc in one column, for as many or as few candidates 
as each voter wished.

The paper ballots from both elections were scanned to produce numerical vote 
files of the kind you suggest.  But the compliance
levels for character recognition were set very high, so many images were queued 
for evaluation under scrutiny.  Those that were
disputed or still uncertain were then queued for adjudication by a Returning 
Officer, again under full scrutiny.  Only then were the
completed numerical files passed to the relevant counting program.

James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.238 / Virus Database: 270.11.18/2008 - Release Date: 03/17/09 
16:25:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV proponents figure out how to make IRV precinct-summable

2009-03-18 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank  Sent: Wednesday, March 18, 2009 3:20 PM
 Well, as the software improves, this would be less of a 
 problem. 

I'm afraid you have misunderstood (or maybe I didn't explain it clearly).  It 
is not a software issue  -  it is a compliance issue.
No matter what software you use to read the images, the Returning Officers 
will always have to decide the level of compliance for
automatic acceptance.  Many more ballot paper images could be processed 
completely automatically if the compliance level were
reduced, even a little.  But such is the distrust of black boxes that the ROs 
in Scotland asked for the compliance levels to be
set quite high.  Hence the symbol correction queue.  The adjudication queue 
is quite separate and will always exist.


 Also, I think one of the issues in Scotland was poor 
 ballot design which overloaded the ballot. 

There's lots I could write about this, but I don't have time right now.  The 
real problem was with the MMP elections.  The large
processing queues and delays resulted from the need for adjudication on 
anything that did not conform, including a ballot sheet with
only one vote recorded on it instead of the expected two.

If you want to know more about this, see:   
  Rejected Ballot Papers in the Scottish Elections 2007 
  http://www.epop07.com/papers/Gilmour-Pre-Conf-Paper-31Aug07.pdf


 A better layout 
 might have been two separate ballots for each person, so it 
 is obvious that they are separate.

Separate ballot papers were used for the two MMP votes in the elections in 1999 
and 2003.  The combined ballot sheet (following New
Zealand) was introduced in 2007 to address some very large problems in voter 
understanding of how MMP really works.  For more on
that, see the report of the Arbuthnott Commission:   
  
http://www.scotlandoffice.gov.uk/scotlandoffice/files/Final%20version%20of%20report.pdf



 Abd's proposal is that lots of people would take images of 
 the ballots and each ballot would have an ID number added 
 (after it is taken out of the ballot box) for easy reference.

All ballot papers in the UK have a unique number printed on the back.  For 
electronic processing, they also have a unique barcode on
the back that goes with the scanned image.  The system is designed, both paper 
and electronic, so that no-one can see, at the same
time, both the face and reverse of a ballot paper or an image of a ballot 
paper.  You need a Court Order for authority to look at
both the face and reverse of the ballot papers, and that will be granted only 
in cases where there is good evidence for fraud to be
suspected.

James Gilmour


No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.238 / Virus Database: 270.11.18/2008 - Release Date: 03/17/09 
16:25:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] IRV proponents figure out how to make IRV precinct-summable

2009-03-18 Thread James Gilmour
Raph Frank  Sent: Wednesday, March 18, 2009 5:54 PM
  2009/3/18 James Gilmour jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk:
  I'm afraid you have misunderstood (or maybe I didn't explain it 
  clearly).  It is not a software issue  -  it is a compliance issue. No 
  matter what software you use to read the images, the Returning 
  Officers will always have to decide the level of compliance for 
  automatic acceptance.
 
 By compliance, do you mean the confidence level that the 
 software outputs?

I do not know how the DRS software works, so I cannot answer the question as 
asked.  But as I understand, some form of intelligent
OCR is used to read the image to produce the vote vector for each ballot 
paper.  The system can be set to accept or reject various
forms of the same vote mark.  This is, for example, an unbelievably large 
number of ways of marking a 1 in a square in the
voting column!!  What angle away from vertical is acceptable?  What degree of 
curl in the pencil stroke is acceptable?  Does it have
an up-stroke so that it might confused with a 7? etc, etc, etc.  You have to 
see the images (hundreds of them) to appreciate the
variation in what is actually done by voters.  For the 2007 elections, an image 
was queued for evaluation if even the tiniest part
of a vote mark (X or a number, depending on the election)  went over the 
border into the next box.  Also queued for evaluation
were all ballot papers that had ANY additional marks at all anywhere on the 
face of the paper.

As I understand it, there are settable parameters in the system that could be 
set to accept or reject all of the variations
described above, and many more.  The compliance requirements were set high 
because when I and many others looked at the symbol
images queued for evaluation, we said it was obvious which most of them were.  
But they had been queued because, in some way, they
did not comply with the parameters set and agreed by the Returning Officers.


 Multiple independent images, processed by different people 
 help with this issue.  You would only need to check ballots 
 where there is disagreement.

I am not sure what you meant here, but if there was any disagreement about the 
symbol correction at the evaluation stage, the
image was queued for adjudication by a Returning Officer.  There were 
comparatively few queued for that reason.  But there were very
large numbers queued for adjudication for other reasons, so that the candidates 
and their agents would be happy with the decisions.

The system used in 2007 was non-heuristic, but there was a heuristic version 
available that would learn from the symbol
corrections at the evaluation stage and so progressively queue fewer and fewer 
images for evaluation.  But that would have been a
black box step too far, at least on that occasion which was the first time 
any of the countries in the UK had used electronic
counting for ALL its elections.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.238 / Virus Database: 270.11.18/2008 - Release Date: 03/17/09 
16:25:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] language/framing quibble

2009-03-05 Thread James Gilmour
Fred Gohlke   Sent: Thursday, March 05, 2009 1:24 PM
 The essence of democracy is not what you want, it is what the 
 people of Owego want.
 
 The only way we can find out who the people of Owego want to be their 
 mayor is to ask them.  Our present electoral methods do not ask the 
 people who they want, they tell the people what choices they have. 
 Campaigning is not asking, it is telling.
 
 The failure of our political system is that it is not an asking 
 mechanism, it is a telling mechanism.  In spite of the advances in 
 transportation, communication and data processing over the past 200-odd 
 years, we have not yet devised a means of asking the people to make 
 their own political decisions.  We have the means, but not the method.
 
 My purpose is to devise a practical method of asking the 
 people of Owego who they want as their mayor.

Fred, there are two fundamental flaws in your approach.  The person they want 
may well not want the job.  So the choice has to be
narrowed to those who would be prepared to take on the job.  If that were not 
the case, everyone in Owego could offer themselves for
the post, but that doesn't happen.

The second flaw is that the reality is that not everyone wants make their own 
political decisions, and the proportion in that
category is a surprisingly (and disappointingly ?) large.  You may say that is 
the result of decades or centuries of conditioning
and of being denied the opportunity to make their own political decisions.  But 
I don't see any evidence of a groundswell of popular
opinion or activity that suggest that is going to change any time soon, at 
least, not here in the UK.  Indeed, I see (and
experience) evidence that well-informed people surprisingly do not want to 
participate in decision-making, even when it affects them
personally and very directly.

James Gilmour
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.237 / Virus Database: 270.11.8/1984 - Release Date: 03/04/09 
19:17:00



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV and weighted positional methods

2009-02-01 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp  Sent: Sunday, February 01, 2009 6:44 PM
 OK James. I stand corrected.
 
 Although I think that Cincinnati OH defeated an STV plan for 
 just such a reason - that the STV plan reduced the number of 
 votes that each voter could cast for at-large seats.

I am not familiar with that particular case, but the usual reason why STV-PR is 
defeated is because the partisan interests realise
that they would loose power if they won seats in proportion to their support 
among the voters.  The larger parties in particular do
not want the voters to be represented fairly, that is, for the parties to win 
seats proportionately, in accordance with the wishes
of the voters.  Those parties want to keep a voting system that consistently 
distorts the voters' wishes in favour of their parties.


 I suppose district seats is a good alternative that tends to 
 represent minority groups who live dispersed in different districts.

No, this would NOT be good alternative, because the largest minority could win 
every one of the single-member district seats and so
leave a majority of the voters without representation.  NO voting system based 
on single-member districts can ensure fair and
balanced representation of the voters.  To achieve fair representation it is 
necessary to elect several members together  -  the
more elected together, the  more proportional the outcome will be.   Electing 
more together also increases the diversity of views
that can be represented directly (by one of their own kind), if the voters so 
wish.


  But you're right that a single ranked or rated vote method 
 if a fair method (unlike IRV/STV) would better allow for a 
 geographically dispersed minority group to obtain 
 representation if they came out and voted in numbers 
 proportionate to their population for candidates who 
 represented their position and if their proportion of the 
 population were at least 1/N where N is the number of seats 
 being decided.

I am afraid you have confused me here.  The best way to provide representation 
for a geographically dispersed minority is to elect
as many embers as possible at large (e.g. the whole city council).  It is 
then up to that minority to make sure they all vote for
the candidate(s) who best represents their views.  If that minority is large 
enough to secure 1/Nth of the votes (or 1/(N+1)th of
the votes in STV-PR), then that minority will obtain one seat, or more in due 
proportion to their votes.

James



 On Sun, Feb 1, 2009 at 11:24 AM, James Gilmour 
 jgilm...@globalnet.co.uk wrote:
  Kathy Dopp   Sent: Sunday, February 01, 2009 6:03 PM
   Are you opposed to any kind of PR system?
 
  Only if you believe that all PR systems only allow voters to cast one 
  ranked or rated ballot for casting a vote for a multi-seat at-large 
  contest.  Voters should always be able to fill out as many separate 
  votes as the number of candidates that they are allowed to vote into 
  office. If two at-large seats, then two separate votes, ranked, 
  rated, or plurality.
 
  This statement shows that the writer has no understanding of the basic 
  requirements of a voting system that will elect a properly 
  representative assembly.
 
  A properly representative assembly is one in which the proportions of 
  seats won by candidates supported by different opinion groups among 
  the voters broadly reflect the relative sizes of those opinion groups 
  among the voters.  (In partisan elections, for opinion groups read 
  political parties.)
 
  If N candidates are to be elected at large and each voter has N 
  separate votes, then the assembly will be properly representative 
  only by chance, no matter how the N separate votes are 
 counted (ranked, rated or plurality.)  In fact, multiple-plurality (at
  large) is one of the worst voting systems ever devised.
 
  James Gilmour

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.10.16/1928 - Release Date: 31/01/2009 
20:03



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV and weighted positional methods

2009-02-01 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Sunday, February 01, 2009 7:33 PM
 Obviously I did not express myself clearly enough for you. 
 When a minority group lives concentrated in particular 
 geographic districts then single-member districts give them 
 good representation.

In fact, the BEST method of ensuring fair representation for ALL minorities, 
including those concentrated in particular localities,
is to elect all the members at large.  If the voting support for any particular 
minority is large enough to justify one seat on the
city council, then that's what they will win.  No single-member district system 
can ever ensure that.

What we see with single-member district systems around the world is that the 
boundaries of the single-member districts are
persistently gerrymandered, either to obtain representation for some minority 
or to ensure that a minority that should be
represented is denied that representation.  Even when the drawing of the 
boundaries is in the hands of an independent Boundary
Commission, the requirement to draw boundaries around single-member districts 
can, unintentionally, have either or both of these
effects.

The ONLY way to ensure fair (proportional) representation for ALL minorities 
(those geographically concentrated and those dispersed)
and all majorities, is to elect all the members of the assembly together (at 
large), or at least, if it is a large assembly (e.g.
state legislature), to elect the members from as few multi-member districts as 
is practical.  But that is not enough  -  you also
need a sensitive voting system that will give fair representation of the 
voters' expressed wishes, and that's where STV-PR comes in,
with one single vote per voter.

James
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.10.16/1928 - Release Date: 31/01/2009 
20:03



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV and weighted positional methods

2009-02-01 Thread James Gilmour
 On Sun, Feb 1, 2009 at 1:43 PM, James Gilmour wrote:
  In fact, the BEST method of ensuring fair representation for ALL 
  minorities, including those concentrated in particular localities, is 
  to elect all the members at large.  If the voting support for any 
  particular minority is large enough to justify one seat on the city 
  council, then that's what they will win.  No single-member district 
  system can ever ensure that.

Kathy Dopp   Sent: Sunday, February 01, 2009 10:30 PM 
 Gee. I wonder why in practice that never seems to work in 
 locales where STV methods have been implemented.

Please provide references to the evidence for this statement with regard to 
STV-PR.  (NB My comments related assemblies elected by
STV-PR, not to IRV elections.)


 Simple correct mathematics say that your claim is wrong as 
 far as single-member district systems.

Here are the results of the 2005 UK General Election (UK House of Commons at 
Westminster, London) for the 59 single-member electoral
districts in Scotland in which the winner is determined by plurality.  Only 
four political parties contested all districts and
only candidates of those four parties won seats.  The fifth party contested 58 
of the 59 districts. 

Party   %votes  %seats  
Labour  39.569.5
Lib Dem 22.618.6
SNP 17.710.2
Conservative15.8  1.7
SSP  1.9
16 other parties 2.5

That doesn't present a picture of fair (proportional) representation to me.  NB 
These results are fairly typical of single-member
plurality elections in the UK.

In that election 39 of the 59 MPs (66%) were elected without a majority of the 
votes in the respective single-member districts.  The
lowest level of support for a winner was  31.4% of the votes in that 
single-member electoral district.

54% of those who voted in that election (1,265,097 voters) elected no-one and 
have no representative in the UK House of Commons, the
most powerful House in our Parliamentary system.

If these 59 MPs had been elected at large by STV-PR the results of that 
election would have been VERY different.  NB I do not
advocate electing 59 MPs at large  -  it is not necessary to elect so many in 
each multi-member district to obtain the advantages
STV-PR would give in fair representation.

James



No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.10.16/1928 - Release Date: 31/01/2009 
20:03



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] STV and weighted positional methods

2009-01-28 Thread James Gilmour
Kathy Dopp   Sent: Wednesday, January 28, 2009 8:08 PM
 I see that what you are suggesting as a change to STV such as 
 using the Borda method does seem to be a *lot* better than 
 current implementations of STV,

Now THAT really would be an improvement.  Borda can fail to elect the majority 
winner even when that winner has an absolute majority
of first preference votes.  Don't take my word for it  -  see the examples in 
Robert Newland's book Comparative Electoral Systems
(published 1982, ISBN 0 903278 07 3).  [Robert A Newland was a senior lecturer 
in Mathematics at the City University, London,
England.]

James Gilmour
No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.10.14/1920 - Release Date: 27/01/2009 
18:15



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


Re: [EM] Why the concept of sincere votes in Range is flawed.

2009-01-27 Thread James Gilmour
I had written:
  I do not even think about putting all the
  remaining options into any
  order of preference, much less attempt it.

Juho Laatu   Sent: Tuesday, January 27, 2009 7:24 PM 
 Same with me. It is however probably not
 a big problem for you to pick some other
 product if your favourite brand is out
 of stock.


Maybe, Juho, but that is VERY different from having to put ALL the other 
options into an order of preference  -  which is what was
being demanded by some others here.

As I have said before, I am totally opposed to compulsory voting and I am 
totally opposed to having to rank every candidate when I
genuinely do not have any preferences among some of them.

James

No virus found in this outgoing message.
Checked by AVG - http://www.avg.com 
Version: 8.0.176 / Virus Database: 270.10.14/1918 - Release Date: 27/01/2009 
07:26



Election-Methods mailing list - see http://electorama.com/em for list info


  1   2   >